<$BlogRSDUrl$>

Wednesday, January 19, 2011

The Price of Insufficient Tax Revenue 

A little more than a year ago, in New Jersey to Follow in California’s Tax Footsteps?, I asked this of now governor, then governor-elect, Chris Christie’s plan to lower taxes: “If the governor-elect succeeds in lowering taxes, what will happen?” I noted that lessons could be learned from the California experience, where the anti-tax folks persuaded a majority of voters that they could have tax reductions, while those same voters rejected a tax on government spending. I pointed out that, ultimately, California ended up with one-day-a-week furloughs for state employees that caused traffic jams, and that the price to be paid for reductions in education funding would not be seen “for at least a decade” (though recent reports of plummeting performance by U.S. students and educational institutions, as summarized in this story suggests that the day of reckoning may be sooner than I expected). I also pointed out that “Essential infrastructure projects are left unfinished, bridges are falling apart, cuts have been scheduled for in-home services to the elderly and disabled, income tax refund checks no longer are being issued, and useless IOU notes are being issued to those owed money by California.” Finally, because of insufficient funding to expand or repair the prison system, California was ordered to release 27% of its prisoners.

New Jersey, like California and many other states, and like the federal government, is reeling under the impact of tax reductions enacted at the insistence of voters who object to every possible spending cut aside from the magical “reduce fraud” solution that they foolishly think accounts for the totality of budget deficits. In the case of the federal government, I have repeatedly asked the tax-cut advocates to identify the spending cuts they wish to make. I did this most recently in The Grand Delusion: Balancing the Federal Budget Without Tax Increases. Though I did not ask this question specifically with respect to New Jersey’s fiscal crisis, I should have done so, though holding up California’s experience as an indicator made, and continues to make, sense.

Now comes news, news that very likely would have had an impact on voter decisions had it been released before, rather than after, the election. New Jersey’s governor insisted that one way of balancing the state budget was to reduce or eliminate state payments to local governments. And so the cuts were imposed. Faced with reduced state assistance, Camden City Council, as explained in numerous reports, such as this one, has voted to cut up to one-fourth of the city work force, including almost half of the city’s police officers and one-third of its firefighters. Some residents claim that they will be “buying weapons” because they will “have to defend ourselves [and] our families.” The head of the City Council put the blame on the state’s decision to reduce city funding. In response, according to this report, the governor essentially replied, “Don’t blame me.” He claims that the council is at fault, because “they’re the ones who have been managing the city for all these years.” Christie supported the notion of having the city of Camden “spend less.” And so it will. Christie justified his decision in part on corrupt city politicians that he had helped, in his former position as U.S. Attorney for New Jersey, put in jail. However, barring evidence that these politicians absconded with tax receipts equal to the budget shortfalls in Camden’s past and present fiscal years, the existence and eventual removal of corrupt politicians does nothing to solve the problem. Camden, like New Jersey, California, almost every other state, most other cities, and the entire country, has insufficient resources to protect its citizens, to maintain the infrastructure that the citizens wish to have, and to defend the rights of its residents.

How long until severe reductions in police and fire fighting departments sweeps across the nation? How long until bridge and tunnel collapses, sinkholes, water main breaks, and other infrastructure failures begin to occur at a rate too rapid for even 24-hour cable news to keep pace in reporting? How long until public health systems collapse? How long until voters realize what’s in offshore tax haven accounts, who put it there, and what a difference would have been made had the evaded taxes been paid when they should have been paid? Some people in the anti-tax crowd continue to hide income and assets, even while their precious rate reductions are enacted and extended, because deep down inside, they want a totally free ride. An early installment of the price for that ride is being paid in the form of the looming crisis for people Camden, and later installments eventually will reach far beyond the city that sits across the Delaware River from Philadelphia.

Monday, January 17, 2011

A Whole New Take on Death and Taxes 

The title of the post on Paul Caron’s TaxProf Blog froze my eyeballs in their tracks. It simply said, Pay Your Taxes or We’ll Kill Your Dog. Living in an area that has me rooting for a team whose starting quarterback had been sent to prison for doing such a thing, and having a friend who is very active in dog rescue work, I wondered, “To what could this possibly refer?” Surely, I thought to myself, this must be something going on in an undeveloped or developing nation, where the culture accepts this sort of threat. But, no, I was wrong.

According to the Time Magazine article cited by Paul, this “tax arrangement” exists in Switzerland. Switzerland! The municipal council of the town of Reconvilier, frustrated by increasing numbers of dog owners failing to pay the $48.50 dog ownership annual fee, announced that it would take steps to collect the unpaid taxes, including enforcement of a 1904 law permitting seizure and killing of dogs with respect to whom the tax has not been paid. What made matters worse is that the head of the council, in describing actions taken 30 years ago, stated, “A lethal injection is sentimentality. We took them to a knacker’s yard, shot them in the head, and it was done . . . Euthanasia is for humans, and in our era, we’re not going to dilute the truth.” In reaction to the not unexpected expressions of outrage and dumbfoundedness, the council head explained that the unpaid taxes could be paid in installments and that killing dogs would be an extreme and unlikely outcome. He added, “This isn’t about eliminating all the little doggies! We don’t even have an extermination worker – our police forces aren’t even armed!”

A reader of TaxProf Blog pointed out that there are jurisdictions within the United States that have similar laws on the books. A reader named “US Law” quoted section 19-20-2 of the West Virginia Code:
It shall be the duty of the county assessor and his or her deputies of each county within this state, at the time they are making assessment of the personal property within such county, to assess and collect a head tax of three dollars on each dog, male or female; and in addition to the above, the assessor and his or her deputies shall have the further duty of collecting any such head tax on dogs as may be levied by the ordinances of each and every municipality within the county. However, no head tax may be levied against any guide or support dog especially trained for the purpose of serving as a guide, leader, listener or support for a blind person, deaf person or a person who is physically or mentally disabled because of any neurological, muscular, skeletal or psychological disorder that causes weakness or inability to perform any function. Guide or support dogs must be registered as provided by this section. In the event that the owner, keeper or person having in his or her possession or allowing to remain on any premises under his or her control any dog above the age of six months, shall refuse or fail to pay such tax, when the same is assessed or within fifteen days thereafter, to the assessor or deputy assessor, then such assessor or deputy assessor shall certify such tax to the county dog warden; if there be no county dog warden he or she shall certify such tax to the county sheriff, who shall take charge of the dog for which the tax is delinquent and impound the same for a period of fifteen days, for which service he or she shall be allowed a fee of one dollar and fifty cents to be charged against such delinquent taxpayer in addition to the taxes herein provided for. In case the tax and impounding charge herein provided for shall not have been paid within the period of fifteen days, then the sheriff may sell the impounded dog and deduct the impounding charge and the delinquent tax from the amount received therefor, and return the balance, if any, to the delinquent taxpayer. Should the sheriff fail to sell the dog so impounded within the time specified herein, he or she shall kill such dog and dispose of its body.
West Virginia is not alone with this tax enforcement approach. Under section 17-526 of the Nebraska Revised Statutes, the approach is similar:
Second-class cities and villages may, by ordinance entered at large on the proper journal or record of proceedings of such municipality, impose a license tax in an amount which shall be determined by the governing body of such second-class city or village for each dog or other animal, on the owners and harborers of dogs and other animals, and enforce the same by appropriate penalties, and cause the destruction of any dog or other animal, for which the owner or harborer shall refuse or neglect to pay such license tax.
In Utah, section 10-8-65 of the Municipal Code states, “They may license, tax, regulate or prohibit the keeping of dogs, and authorize the destruction, sale or other disposal of the same when at large contrary to ordinance.” There probably are similar provisions in the statutes of other states. So before fingers are pointed at Switzerland, it would be prudent to engage in some self-examination of laws in the United States. There is something absurd about inflicting punishment on the dog, who hasn’t done anything wrong, rather than on the owner. Fortunately, there are some states that do not take out the tax nonpayment on the dog, but instead look to the imposition of fines on the deadbeat owner, at times classifying the failure to pay as a misdemeanor.

Though statutes providing for the killing of dogs with respect to whom their owners have not paid applicable taxes have been on the books for quite some time, there is something not only immoral but also illogical in the killing aspect of the remedy. If a person does not pay a vehicle registration fee, do states confiscate the vehicle and then send it to the car smashing machine at the junkyard? No, the state auctions the vehicle in an attempt to raise revenue. If a person does not pay real property taxes, the state or local government files a tax lien and eventually can end up owning the property. Does it burn down the house or other structures on the property? No, again, it sells the property at a tax sale. If a person fails to pay an occupation tax, the state might shut down the person’s business, but it doesn’t put the person on death row. If a person does not pay a per capita tax, does the local government cut off the person’s head? Hardly.

The only good thing to come out of the Switzerland story is that it makes people aware of something formerly unnoticed and might trigger movements to take these laws off the books. Sometimes, the best way to teach a lesson to others is to set a good example. Are you listening, state legislators?

Friday, January 14, 2011

Julian Block Talks Tax with Married, Divorced, and Other Couples 

To be precise, Julian Block isn’t so much talking with the married and divorce, but sharing explanations of pretty much every sort of issue couples will encounter, beginning with a set of questions and answers that he has constructed to put the issues into realistic contexts. He does all of this in “Julian Block’s Tax Tips for Marriage and Divorce.” The range of topics and the folksy way in which Julian defuses the anxiety that accompanies tax questions for most people are impressive considering he had a mere 120 pages in which to tackle puzzlers such as joint returns, tax traps for same-sex couples, property settlements, dependency exemptions for children of divorced parents, taxation of social security benefits, withholding, and even the tax consequences of having an affair. It’s not surprising that Julian moves through these topics with clear explanations written for taxpayers rather than tax professionals. In my reviews of his earlier books, I noted the same strengths in his writing. "MARRIAGE AND DIVORCE: Savvy Ways For Persons Marrying, Married Or Divorcing To Trim Their Taxes - And They’re Legal" was reviewed in Tax and Relationships: A Book to Read and Give (Feb. 2006), "THE HOME SELLER’S GUIDE TO TAX SAVINGS: Simple Ways For Any Seller To Lower Taxes To The Legal Minimum," in A New Book on Taxation of Residence Sales: Don't Leave Home Without It (Aug. 2006), "TAX TIPS FOR SMALL BUSINESSES: Savvy Ways For Writers, Photographers, Artists And Other Freelancers To Trim Taxes To The Legal Minimum," in A Tax Advice Book for People Who Write and Illustrate Books (Dec. 2006), "Year Round Tax Savings" in Another Tax Book for Tax and Non-Tax People to Read (Feb. 2007), "Travel and Moving Expenses: How To Take Maximum Advantage Of Every Tax Break The Law Allow" in Tax Travels and Tax Moves: Book It with Block (Sept 2007), and "Ultimate Tax-Saving Resource '08" in Helping Tax Clients Understand Taxes (June 2008).

The folksy style pops up early, when in the preliminary chapter, Julian replies to the question, “It pays for me to file jointly. But I don’t want to reveal my income to my wife. Suppose I have her sign a blank return and then fill in the figures?” with a quick, “Don’t bother.” He follows up with an explanation that the taxpayer’s wife would be able to get a copy of the return from the IRS. We’re not told why the taxpayer wants to hide his income, but perhaps Julian doesn’t know. He also deals with more mundane question, such as shifting from married filing separately status to joint returns, and vice versa, the prohibition against one spouse itemizing and the other claiming the standard deduction, the tax treatment of a surprise “additional alimony payment . . . not required by our divorce decree,” and deductions for contraception and gender change surgery. He also gets into the deductibility of payments to girlfriends hired to manage rental properties or to do office work for the taxpayer.

Part 1 focuses on filing status, and includes discussion of when status is determined, amending returns, the scope of joint liability on joint returns, and the advantages and disadvantages of filing separately. Julian alerts those immersed in wedding preparations that they ought not ignore the tax issues. He explains the marriage penalty and the marriage bonus, and how the scheduling of weddings planned for near the turn of the year provides tax planning opportunities. He also explains the tax treatment of surviving spouses, and tax traps for same-sex couples. Julian’s summary of how the Defense of Marriage Act affects unmarried couples, how it came to be enacted, and what would happen if it was repealed or declared unconstitutional is itself worth the price of the book.

Part 2 deals with the tax consequences of divorce, which can bewilder couples who are going through personal upheavals and encountering an array of financial and property decisions. Among other topics, the tax treatment of the legal fees, the effect of invalid divorces, and the difference between the tax consequences of an annulment and a divorce, and the determination of which parent claims the dependency deduction for children get close attention. Part 2 concludes with a section as interesting as its title suggests, “Unearthing Hubby’s Hidden Assets.” It is a good introduction to forensic accounting, as it explains what sorts of information can be derived from the information appearing on a joint return.

Part 3 explores the tax consequences of home sales by married couples, divorcing couples, divorced couples, and unmarried couples. It concludes with a look at the tx consequences of leaving property in both names while one of the two live in the house.

Part 4 untangles the taxation of social security benefits. Julian explains the computation of modified adjusted gross income, and provides examples to help readers understand what is one of the more complicated elements of individual federal income taxation. Part 4 includes some planning advice with respect to the impact on the computation of taxable social security benefits of filing jointly or separately, and concludes with some reminders about the use of social security numbers in connection with tax returns.

Part 5 is titled “Oddball Situtations,” a title that makes sense when one examines the subtitles within Part 5. What’s discussed in “Having an Affair Can Be Taxing” is obvious and well worth reading. Several of the cases, and most of the issues, have inhabited my basic federal tax course for many years, because they are, as I tell my students, simply too good to pass by. More than a few taxpayers will be interested in “Dependency Exemptions for Live-in Lovers,” for reasons that should be readily apparent.

The book concludes with two short segments. Part 6 examines changes in withholding that might be necessary when taxpayers marry or divorce. Part 7 discusses amending returns.

This is a book worth reading. Someone needing or wanting to make a small gift to a friend or relative who has announced an engagement or shared the unsettling news of a divorce should consider giving the person a copy of Julian’s book. It might not be a glamorous present, but it’s a useful one, and one for which the recipient will be appreciative. The book is published by PassKey Publications.

Wednesday, January 12, 2011

So Who Should Disclose What to Law School Applicants? 

A reader directed my attention to a New York Times article analyzing the economics of attending law school, and to a response to the story. As I pointed out to this reader, this is a topic that has been getting a good bit of press in practice-oriented publications (e.g., ABA Journal), law -related blogs -- including those focused on law students, such as abovethelaw.com -- and in discussions among law school deans, law faculty, ABA committees, and others. Perhaps the significance of the New York Times article is that the discussion is going to expand into mainstream media and grab much wider public attention.

The author makes several assertions which are not quite accurate, but these misunderstandings don’t detract from the basic points, which is that students need to take into account employment prospects, the risk of defaulting on loans, and other economic factors in addition to whatever other information they consider, and that they need help from law schools in doing so by having full disclosure of the relevant, and accurate, employment, salary, and other information. For example, the author claims, “Those huge lecture-hall classes — remember ‘The Paper Chase’? — keep teaching costs down. There are no labs or expensive equipment to maintain.” This may be true at some law schools, but law schools that maintain clinics providing services to the needy while giving law students an opportunity to experience law practice in an environment other than a classroom not only are burdened with what amounts to the cost of operating a public-interest law firm but also are constrained in terms of the number of students who can be permitted to enroll. Clinics are important but they aren’t money makers. The huge lecture-hall classes are disappearing, as more and more law schools limit class size to improve students’ educational opportunities. This change is being reflected in law school construction, as, for example, Villanova’s new law school building has only one classroom that can accommodate more than 100 students, whereas the old building had four. The author also confuses the issue when he highlights a student with $250,000 of student loans in a manner that suggests undergraduate education had nothing to do with the size of the debt.

So though there are a few things in the article with which I disagree, the author is calling attention to concerns not unlike those I have made in the past. For example, in Law Schools, Teaching, Legal Scholarship, and the Economy, where I stated, “What law schools, and their parent universities, need to do is to become honest.” In How A Transformative Recession Affects Law Practice and Legal Education, I predicted that “When prospective law school students begin to realize that the chances of getting a job upon graduation have fallen to the levels faced by college graduates with degrees in those majors that have persistently not been rewarded by the economy, even some of the more idealistic of them will view a J.D. degree as an over-priced ticket for admission to what at best is an employment lottery. When they learn that fewer and fewer law firms are hiring law school graduates because clients are not willing to pay for what little law school graduates bring to the table, some will turn away from the idea and others will join in the increasing chorus to reform legal education.” I also suggested that there will be “some combination of a reduction in the number of law schools and a transformation of what transpires at those that survive” and that “[e}nterprising practitioners, perhaps law firms joining together in collaborative and creative efforts, will form schools focused on preparing people to practice law,” and that [p]roperly operated, they need not charge the tuition rates currently being charged.

The focus of the criticism has been an emphasis on the need of law schools to disclose the realities of job opportunities. It has been proposed that law school applicants should be told that very few law school graduates earn those highly publicized $150,000 salaries when they graduate. It has also been proposed that applicants should be told, and in too many instances are not being told, that significant numbers of law school graduates are not finding law-related jobs when they graduate. Eventually someone will propose that law schools disclose why, after three years of law study, law school graduates are not in a position to practice law, are not near the stage of progress that their peers coming out of medical school have attained, and that some law firms refuse to hire new J.D. graduates for this reason.

Even though I agree that law schools should disclose information such as their graduates’ employment record, and that the information should be specific and free of manipulations such as law schools hiring recent graduates for make-work positions so that the employment numbers can be inflated, I also think there are other disclosures that need to be made by other segments of the legal profession. Why not require legal practitioners to offer full disclosure about the practice of law? Why not require law school applicants to read explanations of how the exciting scenes they see on television dramas and in the movies – cited by more than a few law students over the years as the inspiration for their decision to attend law school – are, like $150,000 entry-level salaries, a fairly rare situation? Why not require lawyers to disclose to law school applicants that there is a good chance they will be confined to small offices, for as many as 16 hours a day, reading through box after box or DVD after DVD of documents and other evidence? Why not require law firms and legal departments to disclose that a specific percentage of their associates or legal employees have concluded their jobs are tedious, stressful, and unfulfilling? Ought not law firms disclose how many newly-hired associates don’t “make partner” and how many choose to leave or are asked to leave after one or two years with the firm? Might not this sort of information cause potential law students to think again about their career decisions? Perhaps law firms ought to be required to explain why some law graduates are offered salaries that are four or five times those offered to other graduates even though all those graduates share a common characteristic, namely, little or no experience. Perhaps someone should explain why there are so many people in need of legal assistance and yet so many lawyers unable to find jobs? Perhaps someone should explain why the connection between those needing legal assistance and the lawyers who could provide it hasn’t been made. Considering that the ratio of lawyers to population is 1:300, and the ratio of lawyers not employed by government, corporations, or tax-exempt organizations, etc. to the population is more like 1:400 or 1:500, ought not each lawyer have 400 or 500 individual clients? Has the legal marketplace failed in this respect? Who is responsible for making these disclosures? It makes sense to require law schools to disclose information about their activities, but the legal profession in its entirety has no less an obligation to be transparent about itself.

The discussion will continue. It will be interesting. It will be contentious. From time to time, it will get sidetracked into other legal education and law practice issues. Whether it will trigger meaningful changes remains to be seen.

Monday, January 10, 2011

Cutting Taxes + Failing to Identify and Enact Spending Cuts = Default? 

It appears that the collision between the refusal to raise taxes and the inability to cut spending is going to happen sooner than I had anticipated, and with consequences that will prove, with effect far beyond words on the pages of a blog, how foolish it is to increase spending without raising taxes.

The Republican members of the House want to cut federal spending. If they fail to cut federal spending, their refusal to raise taxes means that the federal budget deficit will cause the total national debt to increase. The problem with letting the total national debt increase is that under current law, the total debt is not permitted to exceed $14.3 trillion. At the moment, the debt is at roughly $13.96 trillion. This means that the limit will be reached at some point during April or early May, depending on how effectively Treasury can “juggle the books” to postpone the day of reckoning. Once the limit is reached, the nation faces the prospect of government default on the debt, triggered in part by its inability to borrow additional money to make interest payments on existing debt.

The Republicans have announced, as explained in several stories, including this one, that they will not agree to an increase in the debt limit until federal spending is cut. According to the Speaker of the House, John Boehner, “While America cannot default on its debt, we also cannot continue to borrow recklessly, dig ourselves deeper into this hole and mortgage the future of our children and grandchildren.” Goodness, isn’t that pretty much what I said, initially in A Memorial Day Essay on War and Taxation and then in many follow-up posts, when Congress decided to increase federal spending by hundreds of billions of dollars to finance wars while also dishing out tax cuts that chiefly benefitted the wealthy? If it’s so wrong for the government to spend more than it takes in, are the Republicans going to go back and correct their previous errors?

So perhaps it would be helpful to learn what spending items the Republicans wish to eliminate. After all, they want to use their opposition to an increase in the debt limit as leverage to compel spending cuts. According to this report, when asked which programs could be cut, Boehner replied, “I don’t think I have one off the top of my head. But there is no part of this government that should be sacred.” Aside from the continued refusal to identify spending cuts, surely out of fear that lobbyists for those adversely affected by such cuts would descend on their Capitol Hill offices in a stampede, the Republicans are being boxed into a corner by their leader. When Secretary of Defense Robert Gates announced plans for a very small increase in the military budget for next fiscal year, plans that include shrinking the size of the Army and Marine Corps and cutting two major weapons systems, as explained in this story, Republicans objected, suggesting that the proposal puts the nation at risk. Is it possible to imagine how Republicans would respond to a proposal to decrease total defense spending when they go ballistic over smaller than expected increases? Do they truly think nothing in government is sacred? In The Grand Delusion: Balancing the Federal Budget Without Tax Increases, I invited “the advocates of using spending cuts as the sole solution to the budget deficit crisis to identify sufficient cuts to bring the budget into balance.” I’ve had no replies from those advocates that identify specific cuts or even general spending reduction ideas. I’m not surprised.

Republicans had put forth a goal of cutting federal spending by $100 billion, which is a very, very small piece of the budget and quite a tiny amount of spending when viewed from the wider perspective. Yet, according to this report Republicans are now backing down, claiming that cutting more than $50 billion will be almost impossible. Not surprisingly, the Republicans are blaming the Democrats for the inability of the Republicans to identify $100 billion in spending cuts. As Representative Chris Van Hollen explains, “I think they woke up to the reality that this will have a direct negative impact on people’s lives. You know, it’s easy to talk about these things in the abstract. It’s another thing when you start taking away people’s college loans and Pell Grants or cutting early education programs.” It gets better. The Republican plan to repeal health care reform would add $230 billion to the federal budget deficit, as explained by the CBO and reported in this story.

The consequences of a default by the federal government on its debt would begin to appear before it actually “ran out of money.” Even if the default was short-lived, the catastrophic economic consequences would, according to the Secretary of the Treasury, “last for decades.” A protracted stalemate would make the Great Depression look like a walk in the park.

And yet the Republicans, and far too many Americans, carry on as though there is no catastrophic tidal wave building up out at sea. Those who raise the alarm are viewed as the Reincarnation of Chicken Little, as alarmists who don’t understand that it is possible – according to the wizards of tax reduction and elimination – to cut taxes, cut spending, and eliminate the budget deficit without actually identifying and cutting the spending for any specific federal program. Wow.

Friday, January 07, 2011

Statutory Language and Common Sense 

Though I stopped teaching Decedents’ Estates and Trusts in 2009 after 13 years of teaching the course as a “temporary” fill-in on an “emergency” basis, I continue to follow developments in this area of the law because it interests me. It’s also a course that I taught for several years when I entered full-time law teaching, so it remains in a category different from one that is simply “law courses I’m not teaching.” Here’s an example of why the course is both fun and challenging to teach, and no less fun and challenging to learn.

Several days ago, CNN reported on a story with a headline that grabbed my attention: Convicted Killer Could Inherit Victim’s Assets. That’s a very unusual outcome, so I just had to read the full report. I’m glad I did. If I were still teaching the course, the tale would become the basis of an examination or semester exercise question. The fact pattern is simple, though there is one fact in dispute and two that are unclear. Brandon Palladino pleaded guilty to killing his mother-in-law in 2008. The report doesn’t explain why he killed her, and the reason doesn’t matter. For those who are curious, a 2009 report explains that he choked her to death after she arrived home earlier than expected and discovered that he was robbing her house. Brandon, who pleaded guilty to first-degree manslaughter, is awaiting sentencing, and he will be sentenced to as many as 25 years in prison. When Dianne Edwards, the mother-in-law, was killed, her property passed to her daughter Deanna Palladino. Some reports, such as the one from CNN use the word “inherit” or a variant to describe how the property passed to Deanna, but others, such as this one, state that Dianne Edwards had executed a will in favor of her daughter. Whether Deanna took through inheritance or under a will does not matter. Deanna, meanwhile, remained married to Brandon. Two years after her mother’s death, Deanna died. The CNN story states that Brandon will inherit Deanna’s property, which includes the property she inherited from her mother. But another report explains that Deanna “left everything to her imprisoned husband,” which suggests she executed a valid will. In this instance, the difference does matter. What’s in dispute is Deanna’s involvement in the robbery. According to this story, Dianne Edwards’ sister Donna claims that Deanna gave Brandon the key to her mother’s house, assisted in covering up the crime, pawned some of her mother’s jewelry, and used some of the money received from her mother to pay for Brandon’s legal defense.

Wow. As I tell my students, we law professors don’t need to make up our hypothetical questions. We get plenty of material from life itself.

As a matter of law, under what is known as the Slayer’s Act, people who kill another person are precluded from inheriting or otherwise taking property from the decedent. The scope of this rule’s application varies from state to state, many applying it to all homicides, some only to murder, and so on. Those details aren’t pertinent in this case. The problem is that Brandon Palladino is not inheriting from his victim. He is either inheriting from his wife or taking property under his wife’s will. He is not an heir of his victim nor was he a beneficiary in her will. Thus, the reports, about the situation, such as this one, claiming that “a convicted killer is set to inherit a quarter-million dollars from his victim” are wrong. It’s true that the victim’s property, or much of it, will end up in her killer’s hands, but that’s not because he is inheriting from her. It’s because of what her daughter did with respect to her own estate planning.

The victim’s daughter chose to let her husband take her property. If she did this by writing a will that named him her beneficiary, then she made a decision that she was capable of making because her mother’s earlier decision to let her property go to her daughter gave her daughter the opportunity to transfer the property however she chose. If the daughter did this by failing to write a will, then it’s less clear whether she chose to let the inheritance statutes apply or whether she didn’t even give a moment’s thought to the question and unwittingly let the property go to her mother’s killer.

When I taught the Decedents’ Estates and Trusts course, I tried to instill in my students a sense of thinking through all possibilities when mapping out an estate plan. One needs to help a client understand what happens with the client’s property after the client dies. And this is more than simply identifying the intestate heirs or working through the contingencies that trigger alternate beneficiaries under a will if a primary beneficiary fails to survive. It involves getting the client to understand that once the heir or beneficiary takes the property, he or she may use the property for some purpose that the client dislikes, or transfer the property by gift or will to a person that the client dislikes, or neglect to write a will and let the property go to someone who is a stranger to the client, such as a spouse whom the beneficiary meets and marries years after the client dies. There are ways, of course, to reduce the chances of these things happening, such as setting up trusts and imposing conditions on the bequests and devises, but the attorney needs to help the client get past the temptation to think that the unexpected will not happen.

Estate planning is a risky business. People die out of expected sequence. Someone lives much longer than expected. Beneficiaries marry. They divorce. Beneficiaries adopt children. Beneficiaries’ spouses commit crimes. A beneficiary’s spouse or friend might even kill the decedent.

The statute in question blocks the killer from inheriting property from the victim and from taking under the victim’s will. The statute does not apply to Brandon Palladino. The reaction of the victim’s family, and many others, reflects common sense. Common sense seems to tell us that there’s something not quite right about Dianne Edwards’ property ending up, albeit through a two-step process, in the hands of her killer. But statutes don’t always reflect common sense, nor is all common sense codified in statutes. Perhaps if Dianne knew what would end up happening, she would have written a will that kept Brandon from getting the property, by use of a trust. We don’t know what Deanna intended, and there are indications that she wanted her husband to have the money. If she did not, then the experience is yet another example of why people need wills and need to think carefully about what they put in those wills.

It would not surprise me to learn that one or more members of the victim’s family initiate litigation to prevent Brandon Palladino from taking possession of the property in question when he is released from prison. It’s unclear whether the family tried to stop Deanna from taking her mother’s property after her mother was killed. If they did, they obviously failed to prove by a preponderance of the evidence that Deanna also was a killer of her mother and thus blocked from taking her mother’s property. If they did not, it’s too late. So they’re left with trying to find some theory on which to block Brandon from taking the property. It would not surprise me to learn that they tried and failed.

It also would not surprise me to learn that a legislator introduces a bill to amend the statute to extend the Slayer’s Act to these sorts of situations. And it would not surprise me to learn that the bill received little or no attention in the legislature. It would not surprise me that some lawyers started adapting their will drafting to take these sorts of situations into account. And it would not surprise me that other lawyers did not.

Wednesday, January 05, 2011

Financing the FICA Tax Rate Cuts 

Almost a month ago, in Why the Tax Compromise is a Mistake, I described the reasons I opposed the tax compromise, including this concern:
4. Cutting the employee FICA rate. This may be the most dangerous provision in the compromise. Ultimately, it worsens the financial health of the social security system. It dumps even more financial burdens on younger generations. Advertised as beneficial for people at the lower end of the income ladder, the roughly $2,000 tax reduction will be available to all wage earners, including those whose salaries are in the millions and tens of millions. Do those people need even more tax reduction? Why? Certainly not to create jobs.
Had I looked more closely, I would have noticed that the provision worsens the financial health, not of the social security system, but of the nation. The legislation contains the following provision:
There are hereby appropriated to the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Trust Fund and the Federal Disability Insurance Trust Fund established under section 201 of the Social Security Act (42 U.S.C. 401) amounts equal to the reduction in revenues to the Treasury by reason of the application of subsection (a). Amounts appropriated by the preceding sentence shall be transferred from the general fund at such times and in such manner as to replicate to the extent possible the transfers which would have occurred to such Trust Fund had such amendments not been enacted.
A similar provision makes up the shortfall in amounts otherwise collected and credited to the Railroad Retirement Fund.

What will happen is that the nation’s general fund will transfer to the Social Security and Railroad Retirement funds what are, in effect, IOU notes. The general fund will borrow from those other funds, issue special bonds to cover that debt, and in turn use the money borrowed from those funds to pay into those funds the cash that would have been paid into those funds had the full employee portion of FICA taxes been collected. At some point, when the Social Security and Railroad Retirement funds need cash to pay benefits, they will call on the general fund to pay up the borrowed amounts plus interest. Where will the general fund get the money?

The general fund will get the money to repay its debt to the other two funds in one of two ways. The amount in the general fund can be increased by raising taxes. The general fund can obtain funds by borrowing from other nations. Keep in mind that the amount of taxes that will need to be raised, if that route is chosen, is more than the tax cut generated by the reduction in the employee FICA rate.

Consider another possibility, namely, the general fund defaults on its obligation to the Social Security and Railroad Retirement funds. That leaves three choices with respect to the latter two funds. First, Social Security and Railroad Retirement tax rates can be increased to make up the difference. Second, benefits can be cut. Third, the funds can borrow from other nations, assuming that by this time there are other nations willing to lend money to these funds.

Imagine being in a vehicle moving forward at a high rate of speed. Imagine a passenger sees a cliff ahead. Imagine the drive assuring everyone, “We’ll deal with that when we get there, and, anyhow, by the time we get there the edge of the cliff will have advanced into the distance.” How much confidence do you have in the driver’s braking reaction skills and in the vehicle’s braking system?

Consider again, carefully, what is happening: “What will happen is that the nation’s general fund will transfer to the Social Security and Railroad Retirement funds what are, in effect, IOU notes. The general fund will borrow from those other funds, issue special bonds to cover that debt, and in turn use the money borrowed from those funds to pay into those funds the cash that would have been paid into those funds had the full employee portion of FICA taxes been collected. At some point, when the Social Security and Railroad Retirement funds need cash to pay benefits, they will call on the general fund to pay up the borrowed amounts plus interest.” In other words, the funds are being funded with money that does not exist. It’s not unlike the non-existing road surface beyond the face of the cliff.

Monday, January 03, 2011

Sometimes Old Tax Law Really Is Irrelevant 

A recent Tax Court Summary Opinion, Bragg v. Comr., illustrates the dangers of relying on cases decided under Internal Revenue Code provisions that have been amended, and on the dangers of ignoring changes in statutes and regulations. In this instance, it was the IRS and not the taxpayer who made the mistake.

The facts are fairly simple. Taxpayer was married in approximately 1986, and in April 2002, he and his wife were divorced. In the divorce decree, the taxpayer was ordered to pay $400 twice a month to his former wife “without a specific ending date.” The decree also provided that after five years, the court would review the taxpayer’s obligation to make the payments. At some point, the taxpayer and his former wife agreed to reduce the amount that he was paying because of changes in the taxpayer’s financial circumstances. They did not ask the court for a revision of the divorce decree because it would have cost money to do so.

During 2007, the taxpayer paid $6,240 to his former wife through a direct deposit into a checking account set up for her. At the end of 2007, a grandson of the former wife told the taxpayer that his grandmother had remarried in 2006. On learning this, the taxpayer stopped the direct deposits. The taxpayer claimed an alimony deduction of $6,240 on his 2007 federal income tax return.

The IRS disallowed the deduction, arguing that the payments were not made under a divorce or separation instrument. It agreed that the other definitional requirements for payments to be alimony had been satisfied.

The IRS argued that because the taxpayer’s obligation to make alimony payments terminated under state law when his former wife remarried in 2006, the payments in 2007 were not received under a divorce instrument. The Tax Court, however, pointed out that there is no requirement in section 71(b) that payments be made under a legally enforceable duty. It noted that “Although it was once the case that entitlement to an alimony deduction under section 71 required payments to be made under a legally enforceable obligation, it has not been so for more than 25 years.” The Deficit Reduction Act of 1984 repealed the requirement that the payment be made under a legally enforceable obligation. The Court then wrote the sort of sentence that no attorney wants to read about his or her efforts: “Respondent’s legal argument has as its foundation old law and does not reflect amendments to the statute.” The Court noted that cases so holding dealt with situations where no decree had been issued, payments made before the decree was effective, or situations to which the old version of section 71 applied. The Court also noted that Treasury Regulation section 1.71-1(b) had been, in effect, obsolete by the temporary regulations issued under section 71 after the enactment of the Deficit Reduction Act of 1984. In fact, section 1.71-1T(a), Q&A-3 of those regulations states that the requirement that alimony payments be “made in discharge of a legal obligation . . . has been eliminated.”

So what happened? It seems, from the Court’s description of the IRS arguments, that the idea of voluntary alimony payments being deductible did not sit well with the IRS. Yet, there is a good argument that the payments were not voluntary. They were obtained through lack of disclosure. Was the former wife under an obligation to inform the taxpayer when and if she remarried? I don’t know what state law in Washington requires, but what’s the harm in putting such an obligation in the divorce decree? The case does not reveal if the taxpayer sued his former wife to recover the payments she should not have received. If he does recover those payments, he’s looking at a tax benefit rule issue. The case also does not reveal if the former wife included the 2007 payments in gross income. If she did not, and the IRS let her go on that decision because it considered the payments not to be alimony, it whipsawed itself.

Or it simply could have been an oversight by one or more IRS employees. Were the IRS personnel involved in the case doing what some of my students continue to do despite my many warnings, namely, working from “old outlines”? Did no one look at the Temporary Regulations issued years ago? I doubt we ever will know.

With the tax law changing almost daily, thanks to frequent legislative tinkering and hundreds of cases and administrative issuances being delivered almost daily, anyone dealing with the tax law must stay on top of the changes. Speaking from experience, that is a staggering undertaking. But it’s an inescapable one.

Friday, December 31, 2010

A Section 107 Puzzle: Is “A” Just “One” or “Any”? 

Several weeks ago, in Driscoll v. Comr., 135 T.C. No. 27 (2010), the United States Tax Court, in a case of first impression, held that the exclusion from gross income under section 107 of a minister’s parsonage allowance is not limited to the portion used to provide the minister’s primary residence but also extends to the portion used to provide a second home, which happened to be located in a vacation area. The case is yet another example of how courts struggle to determine what Congress intended when examining statutory language the Congress almost surely enacted without thinking about the issue. The existence of majority, concurring, and dissenting opinions indicates the extent of the struggle.

The facts are simple. A religious organization employed the taxpayer, who owned more than one home. One was a principal residence in Cleveland, Tennessee, and the other was a second home at the Parksville Lake Summer Home area of the Cherokee National Forest in Lake Ocoee. After selling the second home in 1998, the taxpayer acquired another second home, but this fact doesn’t affect the analysis. The taxpayer did not use either home for commercial purposes, nor was either home rented to third parties. The religious organization paid to the taxpayer a parsonage allowance to cover the costs of owning and maintaining both the principal residence and the vacation home. The taxpayer excluded the allowance, which increased from roughly $25,000 in 1996 to almost $200,000 in 1999, from gross income under section 107.

The IRS took the position that the section 107 exclusion applies with respect to only one home. The IRS argued that the term “a home” in section 107 refers to one home. The taxpayer argued that the only limitation in section 107 is that the amounts excluded under section 107 be used to provide a dwelling place for a minister, and that both homes were used as dwelling places, a fact to which the IRS and taxpayer stipulated.

An examination of earlier versions of the exclusion, which first appeared in 1921, was not helpful. Originally the statute referred to “a dwelling house and appurtenances thereof” and the transformation in 1954 of this phrase into “a home” was described by Congress as intending no change in the law.

The majority of the Tax Court rejected the IRS analysis for several reasons. First, it viewed the IRS argument as one that substituted the phrase “a single home” or the phrase “one home” for the phrase “a home” in the statute. Second, it turned to section 7701(m)(1), which provides that “words importing the singular include and apply to several persons, parties or things.” Four judges joined this opinion, another concurred only in the result, and yet another did not participate in consideration of the case.

In a concurring opinion, Judge Wherry explained that he agreed with the majority opinion, but wrote “separately to emphasize the limited factual record on which this case was decided.” After noting that he disagreed with the dissenting judges’ position that the phrase “a home” is ambiguous, and that the parties’ stipulations essentially mandated the conclusion reached by the majority, Judge Wherry noted that “[n]ecessarily absent from our consideration of this case are important regulatory consideration which were not fully addressed in the stipulation or on brief.” For example, ministers whose duties require tending to persons living in sparsely populated rural areas may need two or more homes to reach everyone within their assigned area. As other examples, the question of whether the parsonage allowance was reasonable compensation, why it was provided in the amounts indicated, and whether private benefit and personal inurement existedwere issues not before the Court. Two of the judges who joined the majority opinion also joined this concurring opinion.

In a dissenting opinion, Judge Gustafson concluded that the IRS should prevail, for four reasons. First, under the principle that exclusions from gross income must be narrowly construed, section 107 should be limited to one home. Second, the fact that the word “a” and the word “home” are both singular, combined with the fact that in common usage a person has only one home and the facts that, according to the dissenting opinion, the term “home” refers to the place where the minister lives and that a person can live in only one place at one time, makes the IRS interpretation of section 107 “more likely.” The dissent dismissed the majority’s reliance on section 7701(m)(1) by noting that it applies only if the context does not suggest otherwise, and that in section 107, the context does suggest otherwise. To the notion that some people have multiple homes, as exemplified by a person referring to “my city home and my mountain home,” the dissenting opinion noted that the IRS had not conceded the use of terms such as “summer home” or “vacation home” “presumes the existence of a prior ‘home’ that is one’s habitual dwelling.” The dissent added, “The phrase ‘second home’ refers instead to a secondary residence that is not one’s actual ‘home’.” Third, in an argument connected with the second reason, the dissent, relying on the “to the extent used by him . . . to provide a home” language of the statute, concluded that a person can use only one home at a time, and that because the allowance cannot apply to a home that the minister does not use at all during the taxable year, it ought not apply for periods when the home is not in use. Fourth, the dissent argued that permitting a parsonage allowance exclusion for more than one home “would serve no evident legislative purpose.” Five judges joined in the dissenting opinion.

This sort of case demonstrates how frustrating it can be to interpret a statutory provision that does not deal with all of the basic possibilities. It is likely, at the time that Congress enacted the predecessor of section 107, that the thought of ministers owning or using multiple homes did not enter the collective Congressional mind. Of course, considering that, as the court pointed out, the origins and purposes of section 107 are “obscure,” it is speculation to conclude what, if anything, was in the collective Congressional mind.

It is easy to propose alternative language that would resolve the issue, but doing so simply emphasizes the inadequacy of the existing statute. If the language referred to “a home or homes,” the answer would be clear, as would be the case with the phrase “any home.” If the language referred to “the principal home” or “the home that is the principal residence,” the analysis would be fairly easy. The phrase “the home” would be more difficult to interpret than the preceding suggestions, but still less daunting than the existing language.

What’s left are several questions for the future. First, will the IRS appeal, and if so, will it prevail? Second, will the IRS continue to issue notices of deficiency in these sorts of cases, knowing that it would lose in the Tax Court but hoping that it would prevail on appeal to a different Court of Appeals? Third, might the Supreme Court end up dealing with this issue? Fourth, will the Congress amend section 107 to respond to the Tax Court’s decision, and, if so, what will it do? Fifth, might the Congress repeal section 107, the existence of which is difficult to justify under any sort of tax policy analysis? I’m willing to predict that at some point in the future, a subsequent development with respect to this issue will be the subject of a future MauledAgain blog post.

Wednesday, December 29, 2010

To Whom Should People Give Their Tax Cuts? 

According to this Yale Law School news release, two members of the Yale Law faculty and a member of the faculty at Cornell Law School have established a website that “enables visitors to the site to calculate what their tax cut would be, choose a charity, and donate their tax cut amount to that charity.” These three professors “are encouraging Americans to give back the tax cuts just approved by Congress by making donations to organizations that ‘promote fairness, economic growth, and a vibrant middle class.’”

The website in question, Give It Back for Jobs, permits users to select from one of four charities: Habitat for Humanity, the Salvation Army, Children’s Aid Society, and Nurse Family Partnership. I’m sure these are worthy charities, in fact, I know that they are, but the three law faculty don’t disclose how they determined that these four charities, and no others, qualify. Surely there are other charities that meet the tests of promoting fairness, economic growth, and a vibrant middle class. I did not see any option to select a charity other than the four listed on the site.

Setting aside the question of charity selection, there remains another puzzler. Several commentators have suggested that those who wish to decline the tax cut they otherwise would receive should return it to the United States Treasury. Joe Kristan, over at Tax Update Blog, in You First, Buddy notes, “They are all worthy charities, but they do nothing for the entity most harmed by the tax cuts: the government.” Glenn Reynolds at InstaPundit shares an email from Hanah Volokh, who asks, “shouldn’t the only option be to send the money to the U.S. treasury?” and who wonders “do any of [the four charities] create jobs?” and ponders, “Wouldn’t the number of jobs in America grow more quickly if we all spent our tax cut money on consumer goods or home remodeling? Or by hiring someone to mow our lawns instead of doing it ourselves?” Peter Pappas, in Rich Liberals Say Give the Tax Cuts Back, notes that “After all, if they really believe they should be paying more taxes, the diversion of their tax savings to private charity doesn’t solve the problem. The feds are still out the money.” William Jacobson of Le-gal In-sur-rec-tion explains, “I am not sure the methodology is appropriate to the goal, since the money is not paid to the government and the donor gets a tax deduction for the donation.” He argues that “the net effect is that payment is not an act equal to paying higher taxes, in fact, it is just the opposite.” He also notes that “[i]t will be hard to know if the contributions actually represent a contribution of the tax savings from extension of current rates, or just a contribution which would have been made anyway.”

To these questions, I add more. I offer no answers.

Is it possible for charities, whether these four or a broader group, to use this additionally donated money to improve the economic situation of persons who otherwise would be the recipients of federal spending, thus reducing the amount of federal spending directed to these assisted persons? In other words, if these donations provide food for 1,000 families, does that not permit the federal government to reduce concomitantly its food assistance spending?

Is it the government that is harmed by the extension of tax cuts for the wealthy, or is it the middle class and the poverty class? Is the government of the people or something separate and apart from the people? Who are the people?

How can people spend their tax cut money on consumer goods, home remodeling, or anything else, when the impact of the tax cuts for non-wealthy people is that it permits them to continue spending what they’ve been spending but does not provide resources with which to increase spending? Does economic recovery arise from maintaining spending at current levels or from increasing spending from current levels? Does increasing investment in offshore trusts and foreign bank accounts create jobs in the United States?

Would people participating in the Give It Back for Jobs initiative be willing to provide proof that they increased their charitable giving as compared with previous years, rather than maintaining charitable giving while shifting it from other recipients to one or more of the four listed on the Give It Back for Jobs web site? Would people participating in the initiative be willing to give up their charitable contribution deduction for these donations so that they are not being financed in part by reductions in tax liability arising from the deduction?

What would happen if we eliminated government spending on all programs providing the sort of assistance also provided by charities, reduced taxes accordingly, eliminated the charitable contribution deduction, and relied instead on private philanthropy? Would there be an increase or decrease in the number of people living in poverty? Would there be an increase or decrease in the number of people dying prematurely? Would there be an increase or decrease in childhood disease? Would there be an increase or decrease in the number of students graduating from high school capable of competing for jobs in a global economy?

Monday, December 27, 2010

Will the IRS someday Tell Us to Wait Even Longer? 

On Thursday, the IRS announced that certain taxpayers must wait until mid-February, and perhaps as late as the end of February, to file their federal income tax returns. Why the delay? The IRS must re-program its systems to take into account tax changes enacted by the Congress last week but that are effective for 2010. Generally speaking, the delay affects taxpayers who itemize deductions, who claim the higher education tuition and fees deduction, and who claim the educator expense deduction.

Though there are a few taxpayers who try to get their tax returns filed by the end of January, it’s a good guess that the delay won’t change the filing plans of most taxpayers. Many taxpayers don’t get around to filing until March or April, so they probably took little notice of the IRS announcement. A few taxpayers, thinking they have refunds headed their way, who would have filed in February are going to be inconvenienced. They should write a thank-you note to the Congress, for its decision to wait until late December 2010 to do something it has known since 2001 that it needed to do.

The IRS did not disclose where it is getting the money to pay for the re-programming of its systems. Vendors of tax preparation software also face the prospect of spending additional money to update their products and to distribute those updates to their customers. They, too, should write a thank-you note to the Congress.

The more important issue is whether this development is the start of a trend. Fast forward to 2012, when the patchwork arrangement cobbled together last week itself expires. Consider it a real possibility that the Congress fails to deal with the matter before December 31, 2012. Imagine a Congress, deadlocked or simply manifesting its usual inefficiencies in self-governance, deciding by April, May, perhaps even June of 2013 that it is changing the law applicable to 2012. Will there come a time when the IRS tells all taxpayers to hold back on filing until July? Dare it charge interest on unpaid balances? Will it waive penalties?

In the meantime, revenue departments in states whose tax laws reflect Internal Revenue Code provisions surely are facing similar problems. They, too, must re-design forms and re-program tax return processing systems. Who pays? Perhaps a tax on Congress?

Friday, December 24, 2010

Taxation of Social Security Benefits: Inexplicable Inconsistency and Hidden Tax Increases 

A few days ago, a reader of Joseph N. DiStefano’s PhillyDeal$ blog voiced his concern over the fact that social security benefits are taxed “if you make more than $25,000 a year.” DiStefano provided a link to the Social Security Administration’s Customer Help page, where one finds this assertion: “You will have to pay federal taxes on your benefits if you file a federal tax return as an individual and your total income is more than $25,000. If you file a joint return, you will have to pay taxes if you and your spouse have a total income of more than $32,000.” Well, that’s not quite correct.

A portion of social security benefits is taxed if the taxpayer’s adjusted gross income, modified to add back certain deductions allowable in computing adjusted gross income and to include tax-exempt interest income, plus one-half of the taxpayer’s social security benefits, exceeds $25,000. So, in a sense, it’s worse than DiStefano’s reader thought. Suppose an unmarried taxpayer has $23,000 of wages from a part-time job, $10,000 of social security benefits, and no deductions allowable in computing adjusted gross income. The taxpayer’s modified adjusted gross income is $23,000. The taxpayer’s expanded income is $23,000 increased by one-half of the taxpayer’s social security benefits, or $28,000. The taxpayer’s expanded income exceeds $25,000 by $3,000. The taxpayer will be taxed on $1,500 of the social security benefits. It’s more complicated than this, of course, because if the taxpayer’s expanded income exceeds $34,000 (or $44,000 in the case of a married couple), even more of the social security benefits are taxed.

DiStefano’s reader asserts that the “idea of taxing Social Security was to make wealthy people pay taxes.” That’s not quite correct, either. The idea of taxing Social Security was to tax social security recipients in a manner not unlike the way recipients of pensions and deferred compensation payments are taxed. To the extent a person is receiving more than the person invested, the person has income. Congress chose to include some of this income in gross income. In the case of social security, instead of resting the computation on what the taxpayer actually paid into the system with after-tax dollars and letting the taxpayer receive the contributions tax-free while being taxed on the excess, Congress instead chose an allegedly less complex – don’t believe that for a moment – arrangement that presumes that 50 to 85 percent of what a taxpayer receives in social security benefits represents amounts in excess of what the taxpayer contributed. The flaws in this arrangement are obvious. The current tax law makes the percentage that is taxed dependent on what the taxpayer’s income happens to be in the year the benefits are received, which has absolutely nothing to do with what the taxpayer contributed into the social security system. Permitting taxpayers to receive a return of their contributions tax-free, and to then include all subsequent benefits in gross income is infinitely less complex than the monstrosity currently residing in section 86, which one ought not read before, during, or immediately after eating.

If the Congress did want “to make wealthy people pay taxes,” it can and ought to do so by dealing with tax rates rather than by creating convoluted and arbitrary social security benefit gross income inclusion computations. Proof that the Congress wasn’t focusing on “the wealthy” rests in the fact that even when Congress enacted section 86, $25,000 and $32,000 were not annual income amounts separating the wealthy from everyone else. Those amounts were calculated in order to make the revenue estimate from the provision match the revenue that was desired.

But DiStefano’s reader makes an excellent point when he complains that the $25,000 amount has not changed since the outset. None of the amounts -- $25,000, $32,000, $34,000, or $44,000 – have changed. They are not indexed to increase with inflation. Taxpayers who pay attention to details notice that all sorts of tax amounts in the tax law are adjusted for inflation. Things such as the personal and dependency exemption amount, the standard deduction, the tax rate bracket boundaries, and dozens of other limits and similar items are changed annually though from time to time inflation is insufficient to require adjustment of one or another particular item in a given year. Yet the social security threshold amounts, along with some others, such as the exemption amount for the alternative minimum tax and the $100,000 adjusted gross income limit on the active management exception to the passive loss rules, are set in stone, so to speak. They are not adjusted for inflation.

Why some amounts are adjusted and others are not is puzzling. The practical guess is that Congress chose not to adjust an item for inflation if doing so would cause the revenue estimates to make the provision incompatible with budget impact projections. But that could be wrong. Inflation adjustments entered the tax law in response to people expressing concern that inflation was moving people into higher tax brackets even though income, in real terms, did not change. Could it be that Congress responded with inflation adjustments only for items that were the subject of taxpayer complaint? Is it possible that taxpayers were and are more aware of the impact of inflation on tax rate bracket boundaries and the standard deduction than they are of the impact on the alternative minimum tax and social security benefits gross income inclusion computations? Perhaps that was true ten years ago. Surely it is not true now, considering the amount of press that the alternative minimum tax overreach has received. And it’s not unlikely that a sizeable portion of social security benefits recipients are aware of the frozen state of the $25,000 and other tax amounts relevant to the gross income inclusion computation.

What it comes down to is inexplicable inconsistency. All of these amounts should be indexed for inflation, and to the extent this would reduce the revenue stream, it needs to be offset with adjustments to the tax rates. Otherwise, each year social security benefits recipients face a tax increase. But, I suppose, they don’t have the influence in Washington to lobby for tax relief. Perhaps they ought to proclaim that if their annual tax increase is removed, they will create jobs.

Wednesday, December 22, 2010

Of What Value Are Tax and Spending Policy Pledges? 

My Monday post, Tax and Spending Policy Inconsistency: A Nicer Term Than Hypocrisy has drawn the criticism of Peter Pappas, in his Earmark Hypocrisy? post. His response is a bit puzzling.

Pappas contends that “[i]t is neither hypocritical nor inconsistent to favor an across-the-board ban on earmarks while yourself benefiting from earmarks while they are legal.” He then presents an example:
If a congressman proposes that the speed limit on I-95 be lowered to 55 miles per hour and continues to drive at 70 miles per hour, he is not acting hypocritically. The reason his driving at the higher speed limit is not hypocritical is because he does not propose that the speed limit be lowered only for him, but rather that it be lowered for everyone. If, on the other hand, the law changed and the speed limit were reduced to 55 and he continued to drive at 70, then he would be a hypocrite.
The example deals with a proposed speed limit reduction that is not (yet) enacted. The earmark issue, on the other hand, involves something much more than a proposal. According to this report on the matter, “Republicans formally agreed last week to a two-year prohibition of earmarks.” This is much more than a simple proposal. To bring the point back to the example, if the congressman proposing the reduced speed limit enters into a formal agreement with other members of Congress to adhere to a reduced speed limit – perhaps to make a point, perhaps to set an example -- then driving at 70 miles per hour is a breach of that formal contract. It cheapens, weakens, and renders suspect the formal agreement. If the goal was to set an example, it’s a bad example being set. But to stand up in a group and proclaim that “We pledge to drive at no more than 55 miles per hour, and have formally agreed with each other to adhere to this pledge” while proceeding to continue driving at speeds in excess of 55 miles per hour is a classic example of hypocrisy. If asked, “Did you really mean what you said?,” the honest answer would be, “No.” And that is a one-word response that outs the political grandstanding that the pledge turns out to be.

Pappas also takes issue with my point that ending earmarks is a “drop in the bucket” when it comes to deficit reduction. He doesn’t offer any evidence that one-fourth of one percent is not a drop in the bucket. Instead, he complains that ending earmarks is a “budget-cut proposal made by the right” that is being discounted and suggests that every budget-cut proposal made by the right is similarly discounted. The bottom line is that ending earmarks does not reduce the budget deficit sufficiently. As for other budget-cut proposals, I haven’t analyzed them, chiefly because they’re quite difficult to find, and so I’ll let Pappas identify the other ones he thinks are being discounted. A creditor who is owed $1,000 and to whom the debtor offers $2.50 most likely will consider the $2.50 to be a drop in the bucket. As for Pappas’ claim that enough drops will fill the bucket, the problem is that by the time the bucket is filled, it will be too late. One does not fill buckets used to put out fires one drop at a time. One needs a hose, or a pool or lake into which to dip the bucket.

Pappas then takes issue with my point that the inconsistency demonstrated by those who violate their pledges is a matter of principle. Though I oppose earmarks and support the pledge to eliminate them, my annoyance with the violation of the pledges is not so much the lost opportunity to trim the deficit by some infinitesimal amount, but with the lack of principled decision making and the lack of principle. If a member of Congress truly believes earmarks are wrong, and pledges to refrain from using them, then it is flat-out hypocritical to continue using them simply because “everyone else is.” A person with principle who opposes using alcohol and pledges to refrain from its use ought not be defended when subsequent imbibing is undertaken because “everyone else is” doing so. A person’s word means nothing without principle. A formal agreement by members of Congress to refrain from doing something means nothing if those members ignore their own pledge.

The irony is that some Democrats joined with Republicans in making this formal pledge. Some of them also ignored their own promises. There’s also much irony in Pappas’ continued characterization of my positions as from the “left,” particularly when the outrage at even more broken grandstanding promises by Congressional politicians comes from every direction. Considering that I oppose budget deficits because I think they pose a risk to long-term national economic and military security, and considering that I opposed spending money without having the revenue with which to finance that spending and would have been content to see that spending not undertaken, I have been holding to a position traditionally taken by the right. Why the right abandoned that position, gleefully spending trillions while cutting taxes, is an answer that must come from those who think that increasing budget deficits is consistent with arguing for smaller government.

Finally, Pappas notes that legislators who do not insert earmarks into legislation are at “great political disadvantage.” He’s right. By pledging to give up earmarks and following through by holding to that pledge, these members of Congress will not provide to their campaign-funding special interests the goodies that those special interests demand as payment for their contributions to the members’ acquisition of seats in Congress. Well, if that really matters to a member of Congress, then don’t sign the pledge. Stand up and explain that earmarks are important to re-election and that they will be continued. If that’s inconsistent with promises of spending cuts and budget deficit reductions, it speaks not drops but volumes.

Monday, December 20, 2010

Tax and Spending Policy Inconsistency: A Nicer Term Than Hypocrisy? 

It’s a time of year when many people give gifts to each other. The Congress of the United States never fails to get in on the giving action, except, of course, its members are not giving away their own money, but that of taxpayers.

One of the underlying tensions in the debate over how the government should respond to the current economic crisis is the conflict between raising taxes, something seen by some as putting a damper on economic growth, and extending tax cuts and increasing spending, which swell the budget deficit, something seen my some as putting a damper on the nation’s economic future. Much of what is argued in favor of, or against, either position is at best questionable and at worst nonsense, but here and there some sensible arguments are put forth. Ultimately, time will prove one position or the other to have been unwise.

It is reasonable to think that those who line up on one side or the other of the issue would argue, act, and vote consistent with the approach they advocate. For example, one should expect those who think that tax increases stifle economic growth to vote against tax increases and even in favor of tax cut extensions. As another example, one should expect those who consider the budget deficit to be a serious threat and who oppose spending increases to vote against spending increases.

More than a few members of Congress have stood up and decried earmarks, those bizarre additions to appropriations bills that members can insert without opposition, almost always to fund some home state project that does not and would not gather support from a majority of the legislators. There’s nothing wrong with opposing earmarks, for all sorts of reasons. What’s galling, however, is that many of those who oppose earmarks publicly and loudly turn around and slap all sorts of earmarks onto appropriations bills.

The practice of opposing earmarks while making use of them has riled some members of Congress. The best quote, reported in this story, among others, comes from Senate Majority Leader Harry Reid. Reid noted that some of those who speak out against earmarks “are people who have more earmarks than others. If you went to H in a dictionary and found hypocrite, under that would be people who ask for earmarks but vote against them.” Senator Dick Durbin, who inserted almost $100 million of earmarks into the legislation, is reported to have said, “Many of the same senators who are criticizing . . . earmarks have earmarks in the bill. That is the height of hypocrisy, to stand up and request an earmark and then fold your arms and piously announce, ‘I’m against earmarks.’”

Currently pending before the Congress are spending bills that contain at least $8 billion in earmarks. So much for the hoopla surrounding last month’s announcement by Republicans that they were banning earmarks. Senate Minority Leader Mitch McConnell, an advocate of banning earmarks, has 38 of them in the pending legislation. Senators John Thune and John Cornyn, attacked the legislation that combined the spending bills, but were put on the defensive with questions about the 17 earmarks the two of them had placed in the legislation. Thune replied, “I support those projects [funded by earmarks], but I don’t support this bill.” This sort of inconsistency, to use a gentler word than hypocrisy, underscores the madness of opposition to budget deficit growth combined with support for tax cut extensions that contribute to budget deficits, justified by claims that spending decreases will solve the deficit problems, all thrown at us by members continuing to engage in the earmark game.

It’s truly a bipartisan effort. Though McConnell, Thune, and Cornyn are Republicans, Democratic Senators Michael Bennet and Mark Udall, who joined with the Republicans last month in opting to ban earmarks, had their own earmarks in the bill. It will take truly bipartisan reform to solve a bipartisan problem. And that won’t happen until nonpartisan voters take ascendancy in the voting booth.

Earmarks of $8 billion, though seemingly a huge amount of money to most of us, constitutes something on the order of one-fourth of one percent of the annual federal budget. I doubt it’s even quite a drop in the bucket. It’s more akin to a grain of sand on a beach. So what’s the big deal? The big deal is principle. The big deal is the nefarious impact on the economy of a mindset that accepts tax cut extensions and earmarks while complaining about budget deficits and federal spending. When no clear direction is being delivered, those who are being led will end up scattered and lost. Is this what Congress wants? Maybe. Is this what Americans want? I hope not. But it’s what we’ve been getting, and what we will continue to be getting until enough people understand what is happening and solidify opposition to it.

Friday, December 17, 2010

Taking Time to Construct Viable Tax Proposals 

One of the stories that I have been following during the past year is a proposal to revamp Philadelphia’s business taxes, phasing out the net income component of the business privilege tax, and simultaneously increasing the gross receipts component. I explored the proposal in Don’t Like This Tax? How About That Tax?, in Better to Tax Gross Receipts, Net Income, or a Combination, and in Yet More Reasons to Prefer User Fees. I explained how the tax would disadvantage taxpayers with relatively high gross receipts that generate relatively low incomes.

Now comes news that the City Council hearing on the proposal has been postponed indefinitely. According to this Philadelphia Inquirer story, the proponents of the change have agreed to sit down with the mayor and other members of City Council to work out changes that are acceptable to the administration and city council. One hopes they also will be acceptable and fair to taxpayers. The involved parties appear to agree that the first $100,000 of gross receipts should be exempt, and that existing provisions permitting out-of-city businesses that do business in Philadelphia to avoid the tax should be repealed. Under existing law, the gross receipts portion of the business privilege tax will disappear by 2022, and the tax will become, in effect, a 6 percent net income tax that replaces the existing 6.45 percent net income component.

There is general agreement that something needs to be done about a city tax that is too easily avoided by those with access to high-end tax advice. There is general agreement that the tax as currently shaped is a detriment to entrepreneurs conducting very small businesses or simply collecting revenue such as minimal blog advertising dollars, as I explained in A Tax on Blog Writing or on Blog Business?, with follow-ups in Taxes and Parties, in What If They Gave a Tax Party and No One . . ., and in And So Now Philadelphia Listens?. It ought not be difficult to construct a business tax that adequately compensates the city for the services it provides, that provides funding to pay for the costs imposed on public resources by business conducted in the city, that is not avoidable through accounting tricks, that is fair and reflects the taxpayer’s ability to pay as measured by net income, and that is easily administered. The authors of the original proposal, the mayor, and the other members of the administration and City Council who have opted to sit down and work this out are to be commended for avoiding the sort of partisan bickering that lets good tax policy get buried by political considerations and for including everyone in the process who should be involved in it.

Surely there will be more news on this matter in the weeks ahead. And that means there will be more MauledAgain blog posts on the topic.

Wednesday, December 15, 2010

When the Bonus Depreciation Tax Deduction is Not a Bonus for the Economy 

One of the items in the so-called 2010 tax compromise is a provision allowing businesses to deduct the full amount of expenditures made for equipment and similar items. This expansion of section 168(k) bonus depreciation is touted as yet another essential piece to putting the economy back on track, which is pretty much the equivalent of asserting police departments would be improved if they hired and gave guns and badges to convicted felons. This approach hasn’t worked in the past, and it won’t work now. It’s yet another unnecessary concession to those holding lower-income and middle-income citizens hostage.

What does this sort of deduction do? It does nothing for the small business entrepreneur who lacks cash or borrowing capacity to make the purchases. It compels the American taxpayer to foot the bill for the equipment purchases that businesses would have made in any event. It has little effect in terms of marginality. It also fails in other ways.

Almost two years ago, in Just Because It Didn’t Work the First 50 Times Doesn’t Mean It Will Work Next Time, I explained why reviving section 168(k) bonus depreciation and making section 179 first-year expensing more generous doesn’t do much of anything to help restore vitality to the American economy. I wrote:
Does it make sense to increase deductions for acquisitions of equipment? How does that restore confidence in the economy, which is essential to putting the nation back on track. How does a tax provision that encourages businesses to use their limited funds to buy machinery put people in this country back to work? Nothing in the provision requires that the property be built in the United States, and it's almost certain that such a requirement would violate at least a few trade agreements and treaties. What's the point of enacting tax breaks that create jobs in other nations? Dollar-for-dollar, a tax break for creating jobs directly is worth much more than a tax break for purchasing equipment.
Three months ago, in If At First It Doesn’t Work, Try, Try, Try Again, I criticized the Administration proposal to permit taxpayers to deduct the full cost of asset acquisitions made in 2011. I noted:
Such is the life of one of the business world’s favorite tax breaks. Entrepreneurs salivate at the idea of getting a deduction for making an investment. The idea of getting a tax break for swapping cash for equipment of equal value is the sort of thing that makes lower-income taxpayers roil, because they don’t have the opportunity to get, in effect, cash flow from the government in the form of lower taxes by swapping cash for equipment of equal value.
I then asked:
The previous incarnation of section 168(k) “bonus depreciation” as well as continual expansion of section 179 expensing have been consistently hailed as solutions to the nation’s economic woes of the moment. Yet no evidence exists that these tax giveaways have had the claimed effect. Why is it, for example, that during 2008 and 2009, while businesses basked in the benefit of 50-percent bonus depreciation, the economy got worse, not better? Where are all the jobs whose creation was promised when the proposal for the 2008 and 2009 tax break was being trumpeted as the answer? Where is the economic recovery that supposedly was an inescapable consequence of enacting those tax breaks? Similar questions can be asked about the long parade of tax breaks for business investments during the past 50 years. Though the economy doesn’t benefit, though economic fundamentals do not improve, though joblessness doesn’t abate, something fuels the repetitive re-enactment of this bundle of tax breaks. Could it be that it’s good for business? Could it be that what’s good for business isn’t necessarily good for those in need, especially if the funds generated by the tax break go the same way as the excess cash that businesses have been accumulating during the past year and a half, namely, somewhere other than the economy?
If someone does want to buy into the notion that these sorts of tax breaks are good for the economy – and I have my doubts, as I explained in Tax Incentives Can Do Only So Much -- then the tax break ought to be designed to reward those who do something to help the economy over and above what they’ve been doing.

Thus, would it not make sense to limit section 168(k) bonus depreciation and expanded section 179 first-year expensing to a deduction based on the excess of the taxpayer’s 2011 business equipment expenditures over the average of the taxpayer’s business equipment expenditures for 2008 through 2010? Would that not be most beneficial to the businesses that need encouragement, namely, the start-up operations that have a zero or very low average expenditure for 2008 through 2010? Would that not prevent taxpayer subsidization of a company’s routine purchases that are not injecting additional growth into the economy? Ought not there be a requirement that the equipment not qualify for the deduction unless it is manufactured in the United States? Otherwise, allowing a deduction for purchasing equipment made in some other country creates jobs in that country. Strangely, if the equipment is manufactured in the United States but put in service overseas, the cost does not qualify for the deduction. Does this not seem a bit backwards?

The problem is that these provisions are not being written after careful analysis of the economy, its problems, the causes, and the appropriate remedies. They are being written by lobbyists whose goals are not necessarily consistent with the best interests of America and its economy or Americans and their finances, but that are instead aligned with the goals of those with resources sufficient to hire lobbyists to champion tax reductions for those most capable but least willing to pay taxes. It is even more offensive when the provision in question is one that has been repeatedly enacted with promises of job growth and economic expansion but that has repeatedly delivered nothing aside from continued job losses and economic flat-lining. When compromise becomes surrender, the losers don’t win.

Monday, December 13, 2010

Negotiating Tax Legislation: Lessons from Life 

The negotiations over the tax cut extension legislation manifest many of the same flaws that show up in everyday negotiations, and lack many of the attributes found in negotiations between and among serious professionals skilled in working out the terms of a contract.

Consider the primary negotiating stance of the tax-cut-extension advocates. Their position is that retention of the Bush tax cuts will create jobs. Considering that jobs are not created by the poor and middle class, in effect, the negotiating position amounts to a promise that if the wealthy are given tax cut extensions, they will create jobs. There are two major flaws in how this position has been valued by those opposed to extending the tax cuts for the wealthy. First, they fail to consider prior history. This isn’t the first time the “give us more tax breaks and we’ll create jobs/boost the economy/do nice things” promise has been made. And in every instance, at best the nation received a momentary glimmer of compliance. In some instances, the promise was ditched as soon as the legislation was signed. Second, they fail to give themselves protective leverage. What’s wrong with offering, instead, a deal that says, “Give us jobs, and then we’ll give you a tax break.” The tax-cut-extension advocates don’t like that sort of arrangement. Why? It compels them to put their money where their mouths are, so to speak. Yet that is how competent business entrepreneurs, savvy agents for athletes and other service-providers, and professional negotiators attain workable contracts.

The sort of deal-making underway in Washington resembles, not the approach of professional negotiators and seasoned business entrepreneurs, but the false promises of advantage seekers who populate not only every segment of the business world but a substantial part of personal life. Consumer complaints are replete with tales of vanishing businesses, warnings are issued regularly about the risks of dealing with fly-by-night home improvement companies and individuals, and it took the enactment of lemon laws to compel auto manufacturers to honor their contracts. Tales of woe sent to advice columnists are packed with familiar strains of the “he respected me in the morning .. not” song and the crushed hopes of those who believed what the other person said.

Surely a majority of Congress, no matter party affiliation, would agree to an arrangement that rewarded activities that benefit the economy by pushing it past where it now stands. Surely they, and their constituents, understand that the deduction for compensation paid is a tax shelter. If it takes some sort of additional enticement, such as a credit, there are good arguments for providing one. Compare how the tax law generally functions as a mechanism of inducement, which is what the tax-cut-extension advocates are using as their core argument. The tax law, for example, tells people that if they make certain energy-saving improvements to their residences, they will receive a tax credit. The Congress did not take the approach of handing money to people with the hope that they would make energy-saving improvements.

Years ago, the phrase “show me the money” entered into the vernacular. Perhaps it’s time to say, “show us the jobs.” Show us the jobs, the nation will reply in gratitude with a tax break. No jobs, no tax breaks. That’s how tax law inducement provisions work. The “no tax breaks, no jobs” threat is nothing more than bully posturing of the worst sort. There’s a reason the tax-cut-extension advocates don’t like the “show us the jobs, then get the tax break” approach. They know that they’ve created few jobs, particularly enduring jobs, in response to previous tax cuts, and that the nation will not see any sort of job surge with an extension of the tax cuts.

Despite warning after warning, people continue to hand over cash to home improvement con artists, and to engage in behavior they later come to regret when and because they discover they’ve been duped. Perhaps that explains why America continues to listen to, and even cave into, the siren songs of the pied pipers of tax cut grabbing. Yet, just as there are people who hold firm in negotiating contracts and perform due diligence before signing a contract, there are people in this nation who know how to hang tough in working out tax legislation and how to check out the facts before agreeing to a deal. It’s time for those folks to bombard their legislators in Washington with one simple message: Stop Being Duped – Hold Out for Job Creation Before Dishing Out Tax Breaks. I wonder if the Congress has enough of what it takes to save itself and the nation from the con artists and fly-by-night money grabbers. I have serious doubts.

Newer Posts Older Posts

This page is powered by Blogger. Isn't yours?