<$BlogRSDUrl$>

Friday, December 25, 2015

Christmas and Taxes 

In the telling of the Christmas story, the focus, aside from Jesus, Mary, and Joseph, almost always is on angels, shepherds, magi, a stable, and some animals. What brought the family to Bethlehem is mentioned but rarely does it find attention in popular culture, though scholars have invested time and energy in making sense of the first verse of the second chapter of Luke’s Gospel.

One of the challenges is that there are multiple translations of Luke 2:1. Many are listed at Bible Hub. All agree that the journey to Bethlehem was triggered by an order of the Roman Emperor. But what was the emperor trying to accomplish?

According to the New International Version, the New Living Translation, the Berean Study Bible, the New American Standard Bible, the GOD’S WORD Translation, the New American Standard 1977, and the Darby Bible Translation, he wanted a census taken of the entire Roman Empire or the whole world. According to the English Standard Version, the Berean Literal Bible, the Holman Christian Standard Bible, the International Standard Version, the Aramaic Bible in Plain English, the American Standard Version, the Douay-Rheims Bible, the English Revised Version, the Weymouth New Testament, the World English Bible, and the Young’s Literal Translation, his goal was to have all the world registered or enrolled, which is essentially the equivalent of a census. According to the King James Bible, the NET Bible, the Jubilee Bible 2000, the King James 2000 Bible, the American King James Version, and the Webster’s Bible Translation, the emperor’s goal was that the empire, or all the world, take your choice, should be taxed, or registered for taxation.

It is commonly accepted that in the Roman Empire, the purpose of a census or registration was to create tax lists. The creation of tax lists through census or registration was not a Roman invention and has persisted long after the decline and fall of the empire. So however Luke 2:1 is translated, the meaning is clear. It was time to generate a revised tax list.

When one considers all the reasons that a family would leave one place and go to another, tax registration is low on the list. It might be at the bottom. Families flee because of war, famine, earthquake, and pestilence. They make visits to other family members, just to keep up or perhaps for a wedding, funeral, graduation, or anniversary. They relocate on account of changes in employment, or perhaps to escape higher taxes.

I wonder how many people are thinking today about taxes. I wonder how many realize that taxes were at the root of many of the details in the story being retold today. I wonder how many of the anti-tax crowd are thinking that the family ought to have protested by not making the journey and by refusing to register. But that didn’t happen. And that fact makes a difference. There’s a gift there. What happens when it is opened?

Wednesday, December 23, 2015

Is the Soda Tax a Revenue Grab or a Worthwhile Health Benefit? 

When a person favors both good health and fairness in tax policy, as I do, the soda tax presents a conundrum. If, as its proponents argue, a soda tax reduces the consumption of health-damaging sugar, then health advocates ought to support it. But because soda is far from the only item that contributes to sugar-related health problems, tax policy advocated ought to oppose the soda tax. For me, the fairness concern trumps the health concern, particularly because I do not think the soda tax generates a sufficient reduction in unhealthy eating and drinking habits. I have written about the soda tax in numerous commentaries, beginning with What Sort of Tax?, and continuing in The Return of the Soda Tax Proposal, Tax As a Hate Crime?, Yes for The Proposed User Fee, No for the Proposed Tax, Philadelphia Soda Tax Proposal Shelved, But Will It Return?, Taxing Symptoms Rather Than Problems, It’s Back! The Philadelphia Soda Tax Proposal Returns, The Broccoli and Brussel Sprouts of Taxation, The Realities of the Soda Tax Policy Debate, Soda Sales Shifting?, and Taxes, Consumption, Soda, and Obesity.

Now comes a report that a soda tax proposal is being considered for a June 2016 vote in Davis, California. The soda tax is one of three possible taxes being considered to raise money for public works projects. The business community opposes the tax. City council has requested a study to explore the consequences of enacting a soda tax. Some opponents claim that people should not be punished for choosing to spend their disposable income as they see fit. The problem with that position is that when people make choices harmful to their health, the costs of dealing with the ensuing health issues are spread through insurance over society generally. The better argument is that no one has yet proved a soda tax reduces health problems. The Davis city council already has enacted an ordinance requiring restaurants to offer milk and water as the default beverage for children when drinks are included in the meal. It’s too bad parents aren’t already requiring their children to drink milk and water. Some are, but many aren’t.
One member of the council, referring to another California city that recently enacted a soda tax, stated, “Just because Berkeley did it doesn’t mean we need to do it.” That’s true. It would make sense to imitate Berkeley if the Berkeley soda tax improved the health of Berkeley residents. Has it? According to this commentary, it’s too soon to tell. It could take years to acquire sufficient data to answer the question. Perhaps an answer could be found if there were some way to compare how much each person in Berkeley weighed when the tax went into effect, and how much weight, if any, each person lost within the year that followed. That’s not going to happen. Berkeley is trying to gather information about residents’ health, in order to ascertain the impact of the tax, but it will be a while before answers can be offered with confidence.

One huge difference, though, between the Berkeley soda tax and the one being proposed in Davis is that Berkeley is funneling revenues from the tax into health education and health improvement programs. Davis plans to use the revenue for general purposes, which strengthens the arguments of those who see the proposal as a revenue grab.

Monday, December 21, 2015

Winning Back Your Tax Payments 

A reader made me aware of a recent suggestion that every taxpayer who files a timely and honest tax return, along with timely payment, be entered into a lottery. A to-be-determined number of entrants would win a prize, perhaps a refund of their entire income tax liability for the year. Steve Martin and Paul Dolan, who offer the suggestion, think that this carrot approach to encouraging taxpayer compliance would work better than the stick approach currently embedded in the tax law’s system of penalties. They cite a lottery experiment conducted by Kevin Volpp of the University of Pennsylvania, under which patients who took their warfarin medication at the correct time and dose were entered into a lottery giving them a 1 in 5 chance of winning $10 and a 1 in 100 chance of winning $100. Participants in the experiment complied with the medication instructions 88 percent of the time, compared with 65 percent beforehand.

So would a tax return compliance lottery work? Perhaps. Is it worth trying? Of course, unless the top prizes were in the tens of millions of dollars. Would there be implementation issues? Yes. For example, how should the system treat taxpayers who honestly tried to comply but failed to do so because they ran aground on one of the many complex twists and turns of tax law? In that sense, TRYING to comply becomes a lottery of sorts. When is a taxpayer entered into the lottery? After the statute of limitations has expired? If taxpayers are entered into the lottery when the filing season ends, what happens if a subsequent audit determines that the tax return was not compliant and the taxpayer in question won a prize under the lottery? Would individuals not required to file a tax return because they have insufficient income be permitted to file a timely and correct “zero return” to enter the lottery if the prize were a flat dollar amount and not a return of some portion, or all, of one’s income tax liability? Would corporations and trusts be permitted to participate?

The idea of tempting people with lottery participation in exchange for doing something isn’t new. I’m bombarded every day with requests to fill out surveys or consider purchasing something, with a promise that I will be entered into a lottery that pays a trifling gift card or some other token of appreciation. Do I succumb? Only if I would have participated or shopped in any event. So, rest assured I do not fill out surveys asking for my opinion on yarn and needlepoint supplies. Because filing an honest and timely tax return is something I want to do and try to do, and think I have done consistently, I would be entered into the lottery automatically. And I think that would be the case with most taxpayers, because I think most taxpayers at least want to, and try to, file timely and honest tax returns. In fact, because filing a tax return, unlike filling out a survey, is mandatory, opting out of the lottery would require deliberate filing of a late return or a dishonest return. That sort of behavior would be strange, but before the compliant tax return lottery is implemented it might make sense to study the psychological aspects of adopting the proposed lottery.

This might be the sort of experiment in which one or two states could implement, as a smaller-scale experiment. Would it be expensive to implement? Probably not, as it would require some computer programming and the publication of the program. If it worked as Martin and Dolan suggest, the revenue increase would more than offset not only the prize amounts but also the implementation and administration cost. As they point out, lotteries are popular and they make money, not only for the winners, but for the organizations and governments running them. Why not take a chance?

Friday, December 18, 2015

You Mean That Tax Refund Isn’t for Me? Really? 

Readers of MauledAgain know that when I have the opportunity I watch television court shows. Actually, I am usually doing something else at the same time, something within the limits of my multitasking skills. But when my ear catches certain words, such as “tax,” I pause whatever else I am doing and focus on the show. From time to time I obtain material for the blog. That was the case with Judge Judy and Tax Law, Judge Judy and Tax Law Part II, TV Judge Gets Tax Observation Correct, The (Tax) Fraud Epidemic, Tax Re-Visits Judge Judy, Foolish Tax Filing Decisions Disclosed to Judge Judy, So Does Anyone Pay Taxes?, Learning About Tax from the Judge. Judy, That Is, Tax Fraud in the People’s Court, and More Tax Fraud, This Time in Judge Judy’s Court. The latest episode to catch my attention broke new ground.

In this case heard by Judge Judy, a man explained that he did income tax return preparation for members of his family, but did not do so professionally. Several years ago, among the family members for whom he did returns was his son and his son’s girlfriend. They were due refunds, and so he requested a check be sent to each of them. In a later year, he decided to have the refunds deposited directly into their respective checking accounts. He had the bank account information for his son and for the girlfriend, and the refunds were deposited without any problem. The following year, the son decided to do his own tax return without his father’s help. The son, according to the father, “had problems.” So in the following year, the son went back to his father and asked him to prepare his return. By then, the son and the girlfriend had broken up. The son was entitled to a refund, and in requesting that it be deposited directly into the son’s account, the father mistakenly used the girlfriend’s bank account information, so the refund ended up in her account.

Not surprisingly, the son sued the former girlfriend for his money. The former girlfriend explained that at first she was unaware the money had been deposited into her account. She then testified that when she became aware of what happened she contacted her bank. She also explained that she figured it was money that her former boyfriend owed her, had promised to her, and had not paid to her, a claim that was unsupported by any credible evidence. At that point, Judge Judy simply said, “Judgment for the plaintiff.”

There are two lessons to be learned. First, be extremely careful when entering bank account information on a tax return for purposes of receiving a refund or, worse, paying an amount due. Imagine if the son had owed money and the father had used the former girlfriend’s bank account information. That would have made for an even more interesting case. Second, when coming into possession of money, or property, to which one is not entitled, take all reasonable steps to make certain it ends up with the person to whom it belongs.

Wednesday, December 16, 2015

I Got Mine From a Tax Break, So Let’s Repeal It Before You Can Get Yours From It 

When I was a child, I remember being told by various adults that it was not uncommon for someone, or several people, once they climbed to the top of a hill, to try to prevent anyone else from reaching the summit. As the years passed, I realized how true this is, in many different contexts. For example, it is not unheard of for athletes, once they retire, to be in favor of changing rules that they used to their own benefit, sometimes because their perspective of the rule has evolved but sometimes because a rule change would benefit the team with which they are associated in some post-player status.

And so it is not surprising to see the same game plan play out in the tax arena. The news in this report is almost a year old, but it just recently came to my attention thanks to a long-time reader. It is a wonderful illustration of how things that ought not be part of a game get played to the detriment of taxpayers.

In January, 2002, a Florida newspaper reported that David Koch claimed a Florida historic restoration tax credit for a $12 million remodeling of his 1923 villa in Palm Beach. The credit cost the city’s taxpayers $48,000.

Fast forward to 2015. North Carolina’s historic property renovation tax credit had expired, under the terms of its enactment, at the end of 2014. The state’s Republican governor, among others, advocated renewal. So guess who objects? Americans for Prosperity, which happens to be one of the organizations founded and operated by and on behalf of David Koch and his brother. Does this make sense? An Americans for Prosperity spokesperson explained that it opposed the credit because it complicates the tax code and because renovation of historic properties ought not be financed by taxpayers. It is true that tax credits complicate tax codes. But isn’t it interesting that complication becomes a bad thing only after a tax credit complicating Florida’s tax law was used by someone now objecting to tax credits that complicate tax law? There is much sense in refraining from handing out tax dollars for the renovation of private homes. But isn’t it interesting that an organization claiming to find restoration tax credits objectionable was co-founded by someone who made use of such a tax dollar handout?

The same spokesperson tried to justify this inconsistency with an interesting twist. He tried to differentiate expired credits and existing credits. It is not inconsistent, in other words, to object to the renewal of a credit while taking advantage of a similar credit that is in effect. What’s wrong with this argument? If the credit is a bad idea, then it’s a bad idea whether or not it exists. And someone who takes advantage of the credit ought not be first in line to prevent others from doing likewise.

Translated, it works out to this. “I reduced my taxes from a tax break, but now that I got what I want and you want in, I’m going to stop you. I got to the top but I will prevent you from getting to the top doing what I did to get there.” There’s a word for that approach. Actually, there are several words for that approach. Think about it.

Monday, December 14, 2015

The Wonderful Wacky World of Taxes and Politics 

For the past several decades, the Republican Party has been closely tied to tax reduction advocacy and to anti-tax groups. The Grover Norquist “no new taxes” pledge is a creed for most politicians who belong to that party. During the same time period, politicians who are members of the Democratic Party have not hesitated to increase taxes when necessary, and are perceived as proponents of higher taxes. Whether or not this perception is fully accurate, there is an alignment of the parties and tax policy issues.

So what should one expect from a Republican who is elected governor of a state, albeit as an independent? I’m referring to Governor Bill Walker of Alaska. He is an attorney and politician who ran for governor in the Alaska 2010 Republican primary. He lost to the incumbent, Sean Parnell. So Walker decided to run as an independent, and selected the Democratic nominee as his running mate. Walker defeated Parnell in the general election. One might consider this a squabble within the party, not unlike what some expect to happen at the national level if Donald Trump does not win the Republican nomination.

So Walker would appear to be a Republican dressed as an independent. There are more than a few non-politician voters who dress that way. Yet the other day, according to this report, Walker has proposed an income tax for Alaska. There has not been an income tax in Alaska since 1980. Alaska did not need an income tax once revenues began flooding in from its oil production. The problem for Alaska is that oil prices are plummeting, which means its revenues are dropping. When the same thing happened in the late 1980s, a recession gripped the state and, among other things, homes were foreclosed at a rapid pace. Walker seeks to prevent history from repeating itself.

It would not be surprising to hear die-hard anti-tax Republicans brand Walker as “not really a Republican.” Is that the case? Or is he a Republican dressed as an independent who has come to understand the reality of economics and taxes, and the foolishness of opposing taxes on principle no matter the situation? If he is, in fact, considered by Republicans as not really one of them, would that similarly be the situation with voters who are independents dressed as Republicans? Will they feel rejected and turn away from Republican candidates? No matter how the chaos, to use the nicest word that comes to mind, presently infecting the national, state, and local politics plays out, it will affect tax policy decisions in the next few years. The challenging question is, “How?” That remains to be seen. Attempting to predict much of anything at this point is nothing more than guessing.

Friday, December 11, 2015

Tax versus Fee: Barely a Difference? 

A reader sent me an email with the contents of this link and a question. Going through the material, I was grateful that he did not pose to me any of the other questions that popped into my brain. I’m confident he realizes I’m no expert in the definition of “live nude entertainment” or what it means to host a sexually oriented business event.

OK, now that I have your attention, let’s turn to the reader’s question. He noted that commentators have been referring to the sexually oriented business fee as a tax, such as Texas Strip-Club Owners Pressured to Pay Nude Entertainment Tax, and EXPO 2015 To Tackle the Resurrection of Sin Taxes. He then asked, “Is it a tax or fee?”

Though a variety of definitions and distinctions have been suggested over the years, I distinguish a fee from a tax by identifying a fee as an amount paid in exchange for a service provided by a government directly to the person making the payment. Thus, for example, the amount charged by a township for trash pick-up is a fee. The amount charged by a state government or agency for the use of a toll highway is a fee. The amount charged by a local government for filing a zoning variation application is a fee. On the other hand, amounts paid to a government that bring indirect benefits, such as an income tax, is not a fee. A portion of what is paid in federal income tax funds national defense, which in turn provides a benefit to citizens, but there is no one-on-one relationship between the amount of tax paid that ends up financing national defense and the value of military protection afforded to a particular individual or business. Sometimes the line is blurred. The township in which I live charges a storm water fee, but it is a flat amount regardless of the size of the lot or the amount of storm water discharged from the property into the storm sewer system. Is it truly a fee? Yes, in the sense that the township provides a system for removing storm water back into the creeks. No, in the sense that a person who diverts most storm water into on-site tanks nonetheless pays the fee, which makes it more difficult to describe the payment as one made for a direct service.

The reader also asked, “Does it matter?” According to some commentators, for example, Lawrence Reed, one can escape a fee but not a tax, because one can refuse the service. There is some sense in that view. One can choose to avoid the toll highway. One can choose not to seek a zoning variance. On the other hand, one cannot refuse to pay the township storm water fee. Does that make it a tax? Before jumping to a conclusion of yes, consider the income tax or the sales tax. One can avoid or reduce an income tax by turning down income, and one can avoid or reduce the sales tax by turning down the opportunity to purchase taxable items.

This is not my first commentary on taxes and fees. I addressed the question in Please, It’s Not a Tax, and So Is It a Tax or a Fee?. Ultimately, whatever it is called, it ought to be measured sensibly, imposed only after appropriate public notice, hearings, and legislative action, and paid if the legal obligation to do so exists.

Wednesday, December 09, 2015

A Tax Break That Deserves to be Sunk 

Sales taxes generally are regressive. That’s because people with relatively little income spend most of their income on items subject to the sales tax, whereas people with substantial income put much of their income into investments, transactions that are not subject to sales tax. So it’s no surprise most people dislike sales taxes. Of course, most people dislike any sort of tax.

One might think that the wealthy, who aren’t reduced to poverty by paying taxes, would be less frustrated by the tax system. That’s in contrast to poor people, who must give up something, perhaps a necessity, to pay taxes.

Yet it’s the wealthy who scream the loudest for tax cuts. Able to afford lobbyists, and with money to pay people to think up sales pitches for why a tax that affects the wealthy ought to be reduced if not repealed, they have succeeded on several occasions on setting the economy back to the detriment of those who are not wealthy. Over the past several decades they have attacked the federal income tax, and have succeeded to the point that not only national infrastructure, public health, and education have been impaired but even national defense has started to weaken. And now, they have attacked the New Jersey sales tax, to the extent it applies to the purchase of yachts. Very few of us have purchased or will purchase yachts. We know who purchases yachts.

So what’s up with the sales tax on yachts in New Jersey? According to this story, the initial proposal would have exempted yacht purchases from the sales tax if they were used in the state for fewer than 90 days. The governor suggested that escaping the tax should be limited to those who use the yacht in New Jersey for fewer than 30 days. The initial proposal and the suggestion went nowhere. Next came a bill that limited to $20,000 the amount of sales tax imposed on yacht purchasers. This meant that those of the middle class or upper middle class who could afford a boat costing $285,000 or less would be hit by the sales tax in full, whereas those springing for the million-dollar and multi-million-dollar ships would pay effective sales tax rates equal to a slight fraction of what applied to everyone else. The governor vetoed that bill. But the advocates of tax relief for yacht buyers didn’t give up. They came back with a proposal to reduce the sales tax rate on yachts to 3.5 percent. That bill passed the legislature and headed to the governor’s office.

The vetoed bill would have reduced state revenue by somewhere between $1 million and $4 million. The latest bill reduces state revenue by somewhere between $8 million and $12 million. This in a state struggling to provide basic services to its citizens, and yet caught up in dishing out tax breaks to wealthy companies and now, yacht purchasers.

Proponents of the tax break claim that it will help people in the marine industry, such as mechanics, manufacturers, and marina operators, whose sales have declined because they have lost sales to other states. For this tax break to generate enough offsetting revenue, it would need to bring hundreds of millions of dollars of yacht sales into the state. That isn’t going to happen. Nor does reducing the sales tax on yachts mean that the purchasers will use the services of New Jersey yacht mechanics or marina operators. The argument is nothing more than a variation on the thoroughly disproven “trickle down” nonsense that was sold to gullible Americans who are now paying the price for buying into that nonsense.

Monday, December 07, 2015

When Congress Dilly-Dallies on Tax Issues 

It’s no secret to those familiar with tax practice that the inability or refusal of Congress to stay on top of tax issues and move legislation in a timely manner causes all sorts of headaches not only for tax practitioners but also for their clients and taxpayers generally. The tale of repeated short-term extensions of tax provisions as part of a scheme to jack up campaign contributions is oft-told, though unfortunately not heard by the voters who keep sending these money extractors back to Washington. About two years ago, in Let’s Not Extend The Practice of Tax Extenders, I explained why this money-raising game, even if good for the campaign coffers of politicians, is bad for the nation. In that essay I agreed with the point made in an essay published by the Institute for Policy Innovation, a group with whose positions I don’t always agree, and perhaps more often disagree. And now, again, I find myself agreeing with another essay from that organization.

In 'Tis the Season for PITFA, Tom Giovanetti points out the problems caused by the failure of Congress to act in a timely manner with respect to the Internet Tax Freedom Act. He explains that this provision, which bars federal, state, and local governments from imposing taxes on Internet access, has been allowed to expire and then re-enacted multiple times. Each time, the re-enactment passed by a wide margin, demonstrating there is strong bipartisan support for the policy represented by the act. Now, with expiration due on December 11, Congress would need to move very quickly to prevent chaos.

The chaos will be triggered by laws that have been enacted in some states, providing that the moment the ITFA expires, state taxes on Internet access take effect. These aren’t sales and use taxes on purchases made over the internet. These are taxes that are computed on accessing the internet. They can be flat amounts, they can be a percentage of the fees charged by internet service providers, and they can be based on the number of bytes uploaded and downloaded. No matter how computed, these taxes make internet access more expensive, and yet return nothing to the taxpayer in exchange for what the state or locality is collecting. The pre-digital world analogue is a tax on walking to the mailbox to get postal mail, or walking to the store to make a purchase.

And imagine the confusion if the ITFA expires, these taxes are imposed and collected, and then Congress gets its act together, and re-enacts the ITFA retroactive to December 11. Imagine the administrative aggravation of obtaining refunds of the tax that has been collected by the states with these automatically-triggered taxes in place. It will cost money. Either the taxpayers will need to expend time and resources to file refund claims, or internet service providers will need to do so, passing their costs back to the customer-taxpayers. Either way, it is the sort of adverse consequence that arises when members of Congress put re-election ahead of public service.

In his essay, Tom Giovanetti calls for a Permanent Internet Tax Freedom Act. I support that call. He asks, “Does Congress think there will ever come a time when discriminatory taxes on ecommerce and taxes on Internet access will be a good idea? Is that the option Congress is trying to hold open?” My answer is that the option Congress is holding open is the option to raise more campaign cash by holding ITFA hostage.

Thus, I realize that the likelihood of Congress giving up a money-maker is very low. Congress is no more likely to enact a PITFA than it is to enact permanent extensions of the dozens of income tax provisions showing up year after year in tax extender legislation. It’s a miserable way to run a country, but we’re stuck with it until the voters clean House. And Senate. And the likelihood of that happening also appears to be very low. It’s a miserable way to run a country.

Friday, December 04, 2015

Rubbing Tax Penalty Salt Into the Tax Liability Wound 

A recent case, Yguico v. Comr., T.C. Memo 2015-230, demonstrates how a tax problem can spiral out of control. By the time the dust settled, the taxpayers had been hit with multiple penalties.

The husband taxpayer was a real estate attorney. In 2009 he became an equity partner in a law firm. As the court stated, they “thereafter began to see large increases in their tax liabilities.” This is an aspect of “making partner” that not every law firm associate understands. It is not unusual for “take-home pay” to decrease when an associate makes partner.

So by 2011 the taxpayers “owed a significant amount of tax-related debt” and thus took $80,685 out of a qualified retirement account. They received Forms 1099-R, but were unable to “testify categorically that they actually supplied” those forms to their tax return preparer. The tax return preparer provided an affidavit stating that he did not remember receiving Forms 1099-R from the taxpayer. The taxpayers stipulated that they were aware that the withdrawals from their qualified retirement accounts “represented taxable income.”

The preparer did not include the $80,685 on the return. Nor did the return include the 10-percent section 72(t) penalty. The preparer filed the taxpayers’ return electronically just before the filing deadline. The taxpayers did not review the 2011 return before it was filed, or at any time thereafter.

The IRS issued a notice of deficiency. The deficiency consisted of the tax liability caused by including the $80,685 in gross income, the $8,069 section 72(t) penalty, and a section 6662(a) accuracy-related penalty. The taxpayers conceded that their 2011 return showed a $29,416 income tax deficiency.

The Tax Court concluded that the IRS met its burden of production with respect to the penalty because $29,416 exceeded both $5,000 and 10 percent of the tax required to be shown on the taxpayers’ 2011 return. Thus, there was a substantial understatement of income tax.

Next, the Court considered whether the taxpayers could show there was reasonable cause for the understatement and that they acted in good faith. The Court concluded that the taxpayers could not rely on the fact that a preparer prepared the return, because they failed to supply the preparer with all necessary information and because they failed to show that the incorrect return was a result of the preparer’s mistake. The Court also pointed out that even if the taxpayers had provided the preparer with all the necessary information, they did not act reasonably because they failed to review the completed return before it was filed. The Court reasoned that had they looked at the return they would have noticed that the $80,685 was not included.

There are two lessons here. First, if using a preparer, be certain to provide the preparer with all necessary information, even if that means providing the preparer with more information than is needed. It is better to over-include than to under-include. Second, review the return. Whether self-prepared, prepared by a preparer, or prepared using software, eyeball the return to make certain there are no glaring errors.

Wednesday, December 02, 2015

Tax Credit Giveaways Don’t Deserve Credit 

According to this this story from last week, the state of Michigan and Fiat Chrysler Automobiles have agreed to limit the tax credits available to Fiat in the future. Why? Because the credits are threatening to wreak havoc on the state’s budget.

When the credit was enacted, it was estimated that it would cost the state $1.3 billion in lost revenue. Now it appears it will cost closer to $2 billion. Although Michigan terminated the program four years ago, it did not, and apparently could not, disregard agreements already in place. But it has negotiated amendments to deal with the problem. Limiting the total credit is part of the deal that has been reached.

This situation demonstrates why handing out tax credits to companies that promise all sorts of economic benefits is bad business for states and their citizens. The proponents of these sorts of business credits argue that they generate jobs in the state, and that the jobs generate taxes. The wages that allegedly are created are subject to the income tax. The workers spend their after-tax dollars on items that generate sales taxes. They buy houses and pay real property taxes, or they rent, generating taxable income for landlords, and increasing the value of rental properties, thus generating more real property tax revenue.

That’s all wonderful, in theory. But like most theories, it falls apart when practical reality pops up. If the Michigan tax credit had done what it was promised to do, the increased tax revenues should have more than offset the cost of the credit. But that hasn’t happened, as evidenced by the budget deficits that were spiraling out of control on account of the tax credit giveaway. It’s not just hindsight that suggests the state would be better off without the credits. Careful analysis, free of lobbying dollars and backroom deals, leads to the same conclusion. Fiat claims it has added 15,000 jobs, but those jobs have not produced the tax revenues that would justify handing several billion dollars to Fiat.

Once upon a time, business tax credit giveaways did not exist. The nation prospered. Yet those who clamor for a return to whatever they think constitute the “good old days” don’t seem to advocate returning to the good old days when tax dollars weren’t being handed out to wealthy companies and individuals who don’t need financial assistance from anyone, including governments and ordinary taxpayers.

Monday, November 30, 2015

No Money to Pay Tax Debt? Say Goodbye to Overseas Travel 

One of the surface transportation funding bills pending in the Congress contains a provision that would permit the State Department to withhold, revoke, or limit the passport of a person who has a seriously delinquent tax debt in an amount in excess of $50,000. It provides that a tax debt is seriously delinquent if a lien or levy has been put in place with respect to the debt.

One commentator suggests that this approach to collecting tax debts is ineffective. The commentator writes: “I’ve gotta tell you, I had no idea delinquent American taxpayers were willing to have liens imposed upon their property just to avoid paying money they actually have lying around. Maybe it’s all earmarked for a trip to Tuscany? Huh.” The underlying assumption in this comment is that people who owe tax debts don’t have money to pay the debt and thus don’t have money to take vacations. Yet the reality is that more than a few people who owe money, whether to the IRS or another creditor, let the debt sit unpaid while spending money on other items or activities. Legion are the stories of parents who owe child support, don’t pay child support, and yet live lifestyles full of discretionary spending. Some of the cases on television court shows involve defendants who owe money, claim that they cannot pay, and yet are shown to be spending money on a variety of items or activities.

How do they do this? It’s a combination of things. It includes the classic “one step ahead of the bill collector.” It involves moving from one place to another, making it more difficult to be found. It involves stashing cash overseas, beyond the reach of creditors.

Perhaps the legislation will act as leverage. If wealthy Americans are denied passports so that they cannot travel to another country to spend the money they have stashed in that country, and if that other country wants the tourism business, perhaps that other country will have an incentive to participate in shutting down the “stash cash overseas” tax evasion tactic. Or perhaps not. But is there any harm in trying and seeing what happens?

Friday, November 27, 2015

Tax Challenge: Keeping Up With Technology 

Many years ago, New Jersey enacted a business personal property tax. Among other things, it applies to telephone poles, telephone wires, and switching facilities, including those owned by local municipalities. The tax is paid to those local jurisdictions. One of the companies that pays this tax is Verizon. The tax payable to a particular town applies to Verizon if its market share for phone service in that town is more than 51. According to this report, the amount of this tax being paid by Verizon to some towns has been decreasing, and the number of towns in which the tax payments have been decreasing has been increasing. The reason is simple. People are abandoning traditional landlines and turning to cell phones, internet-based telephone, and similar new technologies. The amount of revenue in question is substantial. Even as recently as 2009, Verizon paid more than $50 million in business personal property taxes to New Jersey towns. At least 143 towns in the state are looking at revenue decreases. One town, for example, that collected almost $16,000 in business personal property taxes two years ago will receive a little more than $3 this year. Some towns have lost revenue measured in six digits.

Towns that have sued Verizon have lost. The issue is how market share is calculated. At best, as newer technologies displace old, it’s only a matter of time. Even if a particular town can demonstrate that Verizon’s market share is, for example, 53 percent, it only will be a matter of one or two years before it slips below 51 percent. From a long-term perspective, litigating the market share issue buys little and might not even be cost effective.

As a consequence of losing business personal property tax, towns are turning to other revenue sources, such as the property tax. This shifts the cost of public services from the business sector to the homeowner sector. Some citizens consider this to be an inappropriate outcome. Perhaps it is. But the solution rests with the state legislature. State legislatures, just like Congress, are notoriously sluggish when it comes to enacting legislation that deals with changes in technology, society, and culture. The problem reaches not only taxation but other areas of law as well. When the subject of a tax fades away, a replacement tax is necessary. If a legislature waits too long to enact the replacement or amend the existing tax, the revenue fix ends up looking like a dreaded “new” tax even though it isn’t new in that regard.

When a government enacts a tax on something that isn’t necessarily long-lived, it runs the risk of losing the tax base. On the other hand, imposing a tax on something that is likely to exist for a long time makes more sense. Pennsylvania, for example, does not tax equipment but instead taxes real property owned by utilities. Thus, it does not matter whether the utility is offering wire or wireless communications. The longer New Jersey waits to fix this problem, the greater the chances that the outcome will be disadvantageous for the towns and for those who pay local property taxes.

Wednesday, November 25, 2015

Thanks Again! 

It is not uncommon for someone who has been the beneficiary of a gift, a favor, or a helping hand not only to say “Thank you!” but to close out the encounter with “Thanks again!” It never hurts to repeat an expression of gratitude. Nor does it cost anything. Once again we have come to the time of the year when we focus on saying “Thank you” even though that does not mean the rest of the year is, or should be, thankless.

For as long as I’ve been writing this blog, I’ve been sharing a Thanksgiving post to express my gratitude for a variety of people, events, and things. Aside from 2008, when I did not post and I don’t have any recollection of why or how that happened, I’ve dedicated a post on or around Thanksgiving. I started in 2004, with Giving Thanks, and continued in 2005 with A Tax Thanksgiving, in 2006 with Giving Thanks, Again, in 2007 with Actio Gratiarum, in 2009 with Gratias Vectigalibus, in 2010 with Being Thankful for User Fees and Taxes, in 2011 with Two Short Words, Thank You, in 2012 with A Thanksgiving Litany, in 2013 with “Don’t Forget to Say Thank-You”, and in 2014 with Giving Thanks: “No, Thank YOU!” .

As I stated the past two years, “I have presented litanies, bursts of Latin, descriptions of events and experiences for which I have been thankful, names of people and groups for whom I have appreciation, and situations for which I have offered gratitude. Together, these separate lists become a long catalog, and as I have done in previous years, I will do a lawyerly thing and incorporate them by reference. Why? Because I continue to be thankful for past blessings, and because some of those appreciated things continue even to this day.”

The idea of a finite list suggests that there is some sort of limit on what deserves gratitude. That is not the case. The simple reason for a finite list is the absurdity of an infinite list, which, given enough time, I probably could compile. With that caveat, here are some of the things that brightened 2015 for me:Nine years ago, in Giving Thanks, Again, I shared my Thanksgiving advice. I liked it so much that I repeated it again, in 2009 in Gratias Vectigalibus, yet again in 2013 in “Don’t Forget to Say Thank-You”, and even again in 2014 in Giving Thanks: “No, Thank YOU!” . For me, it does not lose its impact:
Have a Happy Thanksgiving. Set aside the hustle and bustle of life. Meet up with people who matter to you. Share your stories. Enjoy a good meal. Tell jokes. Sing. Laugh. Watch a parade or a football game, or both, or many. Pitch in. Carve the turkey. Wash some dishes. Help a little kid cut a piece of pie. Go outside and take a deep breath. Stare at the sky for a minute. Listen for the birds. Count the stars. Then go back inside and have seconds or thirds. Record the day in memory, so that you can retrieve it in several months when you need some strength.
I am thankful to have the opportunity to share those words yet again.


Monday, November 23, 2015

Old Tax Returns Have Value 

Recently on the ABA-TAX listserv, the “how long must I retain past years’ tax returns?” question resurfaced. And again, all sorts of advice was shared. Three years. Seven years. Ten years. Scanning and digitizing old returns also was suggested, though some think the time, effort, and cost isn’t worth it.

I have written about this issue several times. In Why the “Toss Tax Records After Three (or Seven) Years” Advice is Bad, I shared the adverse consequences to a particular taxpayer of failing to keep tax records. In The Importance of Tax Record Keeping and The Aggravation of Tax Paperwork, I have stressed the need to be careful with respect to generating and retaining records for tax purposes. It may be an inconvenience, and it may contribute to paper or digital clutter, but it is essential.

Eleven years ago, in To E-File or Not to E-File: That is The Question, I noted:
Though some people don't hold onto their tax returns for more than say, 3 or 7 years, relying on the statute of limitations, I recommend holding onto all returns, if for no reason other than to maintain records of basis and to guard against the strange day when the IRS claims a return from some years ago was not filed, which would open the statute of limitations, and which can be rebutted quite easily by providing a copy of the return.
Last week, in a webinar, an IRS expert on S corporations explained that tax returns from previous years can help taxpayers figure out their adjusted basis in S corporation stock. Though I would expect this to be common knowledge in the tax practice world, the IRS apparently thought it necessary to drive the point home. Perhaps they had been noticing the listserv discussion and the many websites advocating tossing out tax returns after three or seven years.

And, of course, it’s not just adjusted basis in S corporation stock that requires examination of previous years’ tax returns. And it’s not just tax returns. When a person sells his or her home, and needs to determine adjusted basis, how old are the records proving the cost of improvements made to the property? Often they are more than three or seven years old. The ability to separate value from clutter is important. Yet very few people learn this skill in school, only some learn it from their home environment, and many end up suffering because they aren’t aware of the need to distinguish between the two. Is it time for me to create and teach a new course?

Newer Posts Older Posts

This page is powered by Blogger. Isn't yours?