Friday, November 01, 2024
Is Tax Neutrality an Achievable Goal?
Tom begins by pointing out that both presidential candidates are trying to acquire votes by making promises to provide tax breaks to particular groups of people or for certain types of income or expenditures. He mentions the proposals to eliminate taxes on tips and social security benefits, to eliminate the SALT cap, to provide tax breaks for families with children, first-time home buyers, and African American men starting businesses. Tom notes that these promises have been made in response to where a candidate was campaigning, the audience the candidate was addressing, or particular poll results.
Tom notes that using the tax code to encourage or discourage behavior violates the concept of tax neutrality. He is correct. He writes that “[t]ax neutrality is a key principle of tax reform that was at the forefront of the Reagan tax policy in the 1980s, and that continued through the 1990s and the 2000s.” I disagree. Tax neutrality has been honored in the breach for many decades. For example, tax breaks for families with children and tax breaks for first-time homebuyers have been in and out of the Internal Revenue Code for many years. Every revenue act that has been passed since long before World War II has included a variety of tax breaks for one or another, in fact, many different, activities and statuses.
Tom writes, “[T]he tax code should not encourage or discourage individuals from buying a home, from going to college, from having children, from marrying, and it should not reward or punish businesses for whether they choose to purchase equipment or lease equipment, etc.” He is correct. For decades I have advocated letting agencies other than the IRS deal with these sorts of issues.
But then Tom writes, “The core philosophical idea behind tax neutrality is that in a free economy, it is not the government’s job to direct you to behave in a way that it prefers.” I totally disagree. Governments at every level must necessarily direct people to behave in certain ways under certain circumstances. With several exceptions, drivers are required to stop at red lights and stop signs. People are directed to refrain from littering. People are prohibited from robbing banks. Laws exist to enforce these rules and even though enforcement falls short of sufficiently comprehensive, using the tax law as a form of enforcement is inappropriate, and in the examples I provided the tax law has not, at least until now, been used to encourage compliance with these rules.
However, Tom then points out, “ You should be able to run your household, and run your business, based on your own criteria, and not based on the details of the tax code.” I do agree that the tax code should not be used to control how people run their households and businesses. But I disagree that people should run their households and businesses based on their own criteria, because without rules that protect people from harm, at least some people would run households and businesses in ways that harm people both directly and indirectly. A business owner’s “own criteria” might include dumping waste into nearby rivers but that is and must be prohibited. However, enforcement needs to be done through means other than cluttering the tax code with breaks and penalties dealing with those violations of law. And so, when Tom writes that “government does NOT know best,” he is overstating a proposition. There are matters on which government does not know best, but there also are matters on which government – provided it is not under the control of a dictator, oligopoly, or cabal – knows best because it reflects the wishes of society, such as the desire for clean water free of waste dumped into rivers by business owners operating by their “own criteria.”
Tom then writes, “Essentially, tax policy should raise the necessary revenue for government while introducing as few distortions as possible.” He is correct. This is a point that I have made consistently for a long time. I doubt it will happen, and though Tom doesn’t offer a prediction, I suspect that if pushed, he would admit that the likelihood of cleaning up the tax law and stripping the Internal Revenue Code of its various incentives and tax breaks is extremely low if not zero.
Tom concludes that “politicians should not use the tax code to buy votes or to reward favored constituencies,” and that this “would require candidates who operate from principle, and sadly that’s out of fashion in 2024 America.” I agree with Tom. Again, I doubt politicians will change their messaging, especially and as long as dark money is used by a handful of people to control the nation and to dictate what they want the tax law to be (which is something that enriches the wealthy and frustrates everyone else).
Thursday, October 31, 2024
A Sad Task: Computing the Halloween “Parent Tax”
In 2019, in The Halloween Parent Tax: Seriously?, and last year, in Does This Halloween Practice Foretell a Scary Future?, I shared my thoughts about the Halloween “parent tax,” which also goes by the name of “dad tax.” I dislike the idea of parents summarily taking candy from their children. I prefer that parents, throughout the year, teach and encourage their children to share, so that when they return from collecting candy they offer some to their parents without being prompted. Children who are taught to share grow up to be different sorts of adults than children who are ordered to do things without explanation or efforts to deepen understanding so that behavior reflects inner conscience. Too many children raised in authoritarian environments grow up lacking an ability to think critically and end up wanting to live in an authoritarian world.
Sadly, a quick google search reveals that the practice of imposing a parent tax on children not only continues but is being practiced by increasing numbers of parents. That is sad. There even is a parent tax form. And it now has reached the point where the computation of the tax now generated disagreement. As noted in this parent tax advocacy, some parents take a set amount of candy no matter how much the child collects and other parents take percentage, with some taking as much as 50 percent and others advocating percentages such as 33 or 20 percent. If this trend continues, the parent tax will become increasingly complicated, not unlike actual taxes. That’s yet another reason to set aside imposition in favor of teaching children to share.
It is worth repeating what I noted in The Halloween Parent Tax: Seriously?:
So although some people think Halloween presents an opportunity to teach children that “the government” is going to “take some of what you earn,” I think it provides an even better opportunity to teach children the concepts of generosity, empathy, and sharing. Those character traits are disappearing too rapidly among certain segments of society.Now, five years later, in a world increasing afflicted by self-centeredness, I wonder what lessons are actually being learned by children who observe their parents taking substantial portions of their candy, not through sharing but by fiat. Thirty years from now, how will today’s children raised under those circumstances treat their children? How will they treat other people? Will generosity, empathy, and sharing be part of their worldview? The reality could turn out to be scarier than Halloween.
Saturday, October 19, 2024
Does the Mileage-Based Road Fee Work for Local Road Maintenance?
For me, someone who thinks user fees should be tied to what is being used, the snag is how the utility fee is computed. According to the article, the fee is based on the size of properties, making it, in effect, a property tax. The fees range from $7 per month for parcels less than 6,000 square feet to $30 per month for parcels larger than an acre. Putting aside the equity of having only four categories of property size, causing, for example, the fee to be the same for a ten-acre property as it is for a one-acre property, the bigger problem is that there is an inadequate connection between property ownership and road maintenance.
The Rock Island street improvement utility fee will be imposed in the same amount on two property owners who own identical-sized properties, one of whom drives a vehicle and the other of whom does not. Granted, the non-driving property owner benefits from the use of roads by vehicles making deliveries or rendering services to the property owner, but that usage is disproportionately less than the usage by the driving property owner. Worse, people who do not own properties but live in Rock Island pay nothing. Transients who travel through Rock Island pay nothing. At least with the gas tax, non-property-owners and transients did at times purchase gas in the city and thus help pay for maintenance of the roads they were using.
Readers of MauledAgain know what I offer as the solution. It’s the mileage-based road fee. That fee reflects the usage of a road by a vehicle, taking into account its weight and other factors. Having a city or town administer that fee at the local level could be challenging, but there is a simple implementation. The fee, imposed at the state level, could be shared among localities that are responsible for maintenance of local roads, though a state might decide to take over maintenance of all roads in the state and benefit from the economies of scale that would exist. The point is that funding road maintenance costs with a fee imposed on property owners is like funding road maintenance costs by imposing a fee on boat owners.
For those not familiar with the mileage-based road fee, I have written about it on numerous occasions, in posts such as It is an implantation of the mileage-based road fee that I have supported for many years. I’ve also written about the fee many times, in posts such as Tax Meets Technology on the Road, Mileage-Based Road Fees, Again, Mileage-Based Road Fees, Yet Again, Change, Tax, Mileage-Based Road Fees, and Secrecy, Pennsylvania State Gasoline Tax Increase: The Last Hurrah?, Making Progress with Mileage-Based Road Fees, Mileage-Based Road Fees Gain More Traction, Looking More Closely at Mileage-Based Road Fees, The Mileage-Based Road Fee Lives On, Is the Mileage-Based Road Fee So Terrible?, Defending the Mileage-Based Road Fee, Liquid Fuels Tax Increases on the Table, Searching For What Already Has Been Found, Tax Style, Highways Are Not Free, Mileage-Based Road Fees: Privatization and Privacy, Is the Mileage-Based Road Fee a Threat to Privacy?, So Who Should Pay for Roads?, Between Theory and Reality is the (Tax) Test, Mileage-Based Road Fee Inching Ahead, Rebutting Arguments Against Mileage-Based Road Fees, On the Mileage-Based Road Fee Highway: Young at (Tax) Heart?, To Test The Mileage-Based Road Fee, There Needs to Be a Test, What Sort of Tax or Fee Will Hawaii Use to Fix Its Highways?, And Now It’s California Facing the Road Funding Tax Issues, If Users Don’t Pay, Who Should?, Taking Responsibility for Funding Highways, Should Tax Increases Reflect Populist Sentiment?, When It Comes to the Mileage-Based Road Fee, Try It, You’ll Like It, Mileage-Based Road Fees: A Positive Trend?, Understanding the Mileage-Based Road Fee, Tax Opposition: A Costly Road to Follow, Progress on the Mileage-Based Road Fee Front?, Mileage-Based Road Fee Enters Illinois Gubernatorial Campaign, Is a User-Fee-Based System Incompatible With Progressive Income Taxation?. Will Private Ownership of Public Necessities Work?, Revenue Problems With A User Fee Solution Crying for Attention, Plans for Mileage-Based Road Fees Continue to Grow, Getting Technical With the Mileage-Based Road Fee, Once Again, Rebutting Arguments Against Mileage-Based Road Fees, Getting to the Mileage-Based Road Fee in Tiny Steps, Proposal for a Tyre Tax to Replace Fuel Taxes Needs to be Deflated, A Much Bigger Forward-Moving Step for the Mileage-Based Road Fee, Another Example of a Problem That the Mileage-Based Road Fee Can Solve, Some Observations on Recent Articles Addressing the Mileage-Based Road Fee, Mileage-Based Road Fee Meets Interstate Travel, If Not a Gasoline Tax, and Not a Mileage-Based Road Fee, Then What?>, Try It, You Might Like It (The Mileage-Based Road Fee, That Is) , The Mileage-Based Road Fee Is Superior to This Proposed “Commercial Activity Surcharge”, The Mileage-Based Road Fee Is Also Superior to This Proposed “Package Tax” or “Package Fee”, Why Delay A Mileage-Based Road Fee Until Existing Fuel Tax Amounts Are Posted at Fuel Pumps?, Using General Funds to Finance Transportation Infrastructure Not a Viable Solution, In Praise of the Mileage-Base Road Fee, What Appears to Be Criticism of the Mileage-Based Road Fee Isn’t, Though It Is a Criticism of How Congress Functions, Ignorance and Propaganda, A New Twist to the Mileage-Based Road Fee, The Mileage-Based Road Fee: Simpler, Fairer, and More Efficient Than the Alternatives, Some Updates on the Mileage-Based Road Fee, How to Pay for Street Reconstruction, Stop the "Stop EV Freeloading Act" Because The Mileage-Based Road Fee Is a Much Better Way to Go, Why Is Road Repair and Maintenance Funding So Difficult for Public Officials to Figure Out?, Should (Will) Implementing the Mileage-Based Road Fee Cause Privatization of Highway Infrastructure?, The Freedom Caucus Doesn’t Understand that the Mileage-Based Road Fee is “PRO-Freedom,” Not the Opposite, and A Mileage-Based Road Fee by Any Other Name?.
Monday, October 07, 2024
Can We Find Tax Forms In “The Tax Code”?
I spared Reader Morris a thorough critique of the sentence. It’s not only the absurd claim that forms are found in “the tax code.” It’s also the use of the term “The tax code,” a term that lacks specificity. There are hundreds of “tax codes” in the United States. The most well-known is the federal Internal Revenue Code. Every state and territory has a tax code, though with different names, such as revenue code. Most counties and many cities, towns, and townships have tax codes. So which tax code is being referenced by the sentence that begins with “The tax code”? Worse, how can one tax code (“’the’ tax code”) include federal AND state tax forms?
It’s easy to understand why tax forms rarely, if ever, included in legislation. Tax forms change from year to year. Legislatures, town councils, and county commissions don’t have the time and financial resources to amend legislation continuously to insert the latest version of a form. At best, legislation might contain a form template, or a list of fields or items that are required to be placed on a form. But surely, the idea that there are “15,000+” forms in whatever is that “the tax code” is beyond worrisome.
I wonder if the author of the AWS Machine Learning Blog can provide a list, with citations, of the 15,000+ forms that are in “the tax code.” Though I wonder, I very much doubt it.
I also wonder how many people read the AWS Machine Learning Blog and consider that sentence to be true. I wonder how many then share with other people their “discovery” that there are 15,000+ tax forms buried in “the tax code.” But I need not wonder how misinformation and untruths spread like wildfire, fertilizing the ignorance that is destroying civilization.
Thursday, September 26, 2024
Lies About Tax Increases on Social Security Benefits
People lie for various reasons. They lie to protect someone from being insulted, thus saying something nice about a terrible haircut. They lie to keep themselves out of trouble, thus denying having committed a crime. They lie to gain an advantage, thus offering untruths to push aside whatever or whomever stands in their way.
Sometimes lies are easily recognized. Sometimes they are difficult to detect. In any situation, it is best to procure evidence that what appears to be a lie is in fact a lie.
That’s the situation I found myself in when I received a political advertisement in the postal mail, circulated by an organization trying to unseat an incumbent United State Senator. The advertisement stated that the incumbent senator had “voted three time for higher taxes on seniors’ social security benefits.” Knowing that the last time taxes on social security benefits had been increased was long before the incumbent senator took a seat in the Senate, I wanted to verify that the statement was a lie.
First, I confirmed that taxes on social security benefits had not been raised since the 1990s. To do that, I examined the amendment notes to Internal Revenue Code section 86, which provides for the inclusion in gross income of a portion of some individuals’ social security benefits. Not everyone who receives social security benefits is required to include them in gross income because individuals with modified adjusted gross income less than specified amounts, depending on filing status, do not include social security benefits in gross income.
Section 86 has been amended three times since the incumbent senator took office. It was amended in 2017 by 13305(b)(1) of title I of Public Law 115-97. It was amended in 2020 by 104(b)(2)(C) of title I of division EE of Public Law 116-260. It was amended in 2021 by 9042(b)(2) of title IX of Public Law 117-2. All three amendments made changes to text in section 86 that cross-references other Internal Revenue Code provisions that were themselves amended. None of the three amendments did anything to change the portion of social security benefits included in gross income. None of the three amendments increased taxes on social security benefits.
Second, I looked to see if the incumbent senator had tried, unsuccessfully, to increase the portion of social security benefits included in gross income or to increase taxes on social security benefits. The organization that circulated the claim included a footnote in its advertisement citing three instances it offers in support of its claim. It cited three roll call votes in the Senate, specifically, “Roll Call Vote #28, 1/25/07; Roll Call Vote #52, 3/13/08; Roll Call Vote #43, 2/4/09.” What did those roll call votes address?
The first, Roll Call Vote #28, 1/25/07, was on a motion to waive an amendment to the Congressional Budget Act. The amendment would “repeal the 1993 income tax increase on Social Security benefits.” The motion failed. The incumbent senator voted against the motion.
The second, Roll Call Vote #52, 3/13/08, was on a motion to amend Senate Congressional Resolution 70. The amendment would “repeal the tax increase on Social Security benefits imposed by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1993.” The motion failed. The incumbent senator voted against the motion.
The third, Roll Call Vote #43, 2/4/09, was on a motion to waive section 201 of Senate Congressional Resolution 21. The amendment would “suspend for 2009 the 1993 income tax increase on Social Security benefits.” The motion failed. The incumbent senator voted against the motion.
None of the three roll call votes cited by the organization in support of its false claim that the incumbent senator voted “for higher taxes on seniors’ social security benefits” involved a motion to increase taxes on social security benefits. The votes cast by the incumbent senator were votes against reducing or suspending taxes on social security benefits. Voting against a tax decrease is NOT a vote for a tax increase. It is a vote to leave things as they are. Here is an analogous example that drives home the distinction: Someone involved with the NFL, wisely or unwisely, proposes reducing the points awarded for a touchdown from 6 to 5. An NFL owner who votes against that proposal is NOT voting to “increase” the points awarded for scoring a touchdown. It is a vote to leave things as they are.
So why would an organization circulate a lie? It does so to gain an advantage. The goal of the lie is to use fear to motivate senior citizens, and perhaps others nearing social security retirement age, to vote against the incumbent senator. Removing the incumbent senator from the Senate contributes to the organization’s chances of controlling the Senate and turning its spending from untruthful political advertisement to enacting its agenda.
So how does someone refute a lie? How does someone undo the damage done by a lie? These are not easy things to do. The first step is to identify the lie. The second step is to explain why the lie is a lie and not truth. The third step is to circulate the explanation to all those to whom the lie was circulated. I’ve done the first two steps. Taking the third step depends on how quickly, if at all, my identification of the lie and explanation of why it is a lie circulates. It is possible that the same or a similar lie is being circulated about other incumbent senators. Hopefully when someone uses a search engine to look for “voted for higher taxes on social security benefits” that person will find their way to this blog post. Hopefully they will share it. Hopefully, those in the organizations who circulate the lie will recant. But I doubt that will happen.
Wednesday, September 11, 2024
The Price of Ignorance
JUST ONE LITTLE EXAMPLE OF UNREALIZED CAPITAL GAIN:It is disappointing that this sort of nonsense gets a life of its own as it spreads from the originator – more on that in a moment – throughout the internet thanks to reposting by people who react emotionally and fail to take time to ask themselves whether it is correct.....your mom purchased her home 40 years ago. She paid $50,000 for it. It's all paid off which is great because mom is living on a fixed income. It is now worth $500,000!! Kamala wants her to pay 25% of that gain even though she has no plans on selling her home. Now mom has to take out a $112,500 loan on the home to pay the Kamala's 25% unrealized capital gain. Mom can't afford that loan on her fixed income with rising inflation so she loses the home she raised her family in and worked so hard to pay off. But don't worry. A big corporation will come in and buy her home and rent it back to her.
They said you'll own nothing and be happy. Do you now see how they will accomplish that? Drain your savings and tax you out of your home!
Capital Gains will also apply to your 401 etc. DO A LOT OF THINKING BEFORE YOU VOTE
The proposal in question is in the Biden Administration proposed budget for fiscal year 2025. The Tax Foundation summarizes the proposal very succinctly and clearly:
The 25 percent minimum tax on unrealized capital gains has several novel features and would for the first time attempt to collect tax on a broad set of assets on a mark-to-market basis or on imputed returns, i.e., without a clear market transaction to firmly establish any capital gain or loss. It would apply to taxpayers with wealth greater than $100 million, requiring a new annual wealth reporting system.Whenever I see a facebook post in which someone reposts this meme, often along with an expression of fear or dismay that this proposal will ruin them financially, I note that even if the proposal were to be enacted, which I very much doubt, I don’t worry about it because I’m nowhere near worth $100 million. I then write in these or similar words, “And I assume you, also, don’t have wealth anywhere near $100 million, so, please, relax.” Reactions range from expressions of surprise to claims that I am ignorant about taxes.
Of course, my attempt to provide free education to the people who so easily gobble up nonsense reaches an extremely tiny fraction of the people who read this absurd meme, even if they don’t repost it. Perhaps here and there someone else who has taken the time to learn the truth about the proposal shares the results of their research efforts. But the vast majority of Americans are being fed what at best can be described as a lie.
So who created this meme? Someone who does not want to be identified. It’s very likely that the person who created this meme isn’t someone who read the proposal and misunderstood it. The explanations, such as the one from the Tax Foundation, are within the reading level of a second grader. The person who created this meme did so in order to influence the votes of the middle class, by fueling fear of something that doesn’t exist. I ask you, who benefits from a lie about a proposal that seeks to increase taxes on the ultrawealthy? Surely those who oppose increasing taxes on the ultrawealthy. What better way is there to get the middle class to oppose increased taxes on the ultrawealthy than to lie to the middle class and claim that the proposal increases taxes on the middle class?
If the American population were not so ignorant about basic tax concepts, if the American population were more willing to do research rather than to treat as Gospel truth the utterances of the guy next to them at the bar or the words of a meme writer who spreads lies, if the American population understood the realities of economics, this meme would be doing the damage of a spitball directed at an elm tree. Instead, this meme, along with hundreds of other disinformation memes and misrepresentation memes, is fertilized by ignorance and threatens to undercut the foundations of democracy. Sadly, the price of ignorance will be paid not only by the ignorant but by everyone other than the handful who benefit from ignorance and lies.
Friday, August 23, 2024
How an Answer to a Tax Question Can Earn Zero Points
The question posed by a reader of the column was a simple one. The reader found a diamond ring and wanted “to limit her tax liability around the sale” of the ring that the reader wanted to make.
The response was surprising:
“Yes, the gain of the sale is taxable. If you've held that asset less than a year, then it will be taxable at your regular income tax rate. However, the big question is your long-term tax rate of capital gains.Let’s begin at the beginning.“Capital gains are defined as the profit from the sale of property or of an investment, and you have to pay taxes on it. (The IRS considers jewelry is considered a capital asset, not a “collectible,” which is taxed at a higher rate.) This rate could be as high as 20% or as low as 0%, depending on your income level.
“This means that if you hang onto the ring for over a year, the tax rate on the income from selling it will be lower.
“Even with the above, it might be beneficial to sell the ring under someone else's name–a parent or a child, for instance. However, that could affect that other person's tax liability, as well. For instance, if your parent is getting social security benefits, having them report the sale could end up making their benefits taxable. Make sure to consider the tax situation of anyone you consider having report the sale, so you can plan for the best outcome.”
When the person finds the diamond ring and keeps it, whether or not legally doing so, the person has ordinary income equal to the value of the ring. That is well-settled federal income tax law. It is a topic that students in a basic federal income tax course encounter early in the course. As a corollary to that outcome, the person acquires a basis in the ring equal to the amount of gross income reported. If the person sells the ring within a short period of time, the person will have zero gain and zero loss. In fact, the sale price of the ring is a major factor in determining the value of the ring at the time it was sold, with the passing of a few weeks or months having no practical impact on the valuation issue. That means the determination of whether the gain is short-term or long-term is an issue that does not need to be addressed. Of course, if the reader holds the ring for a longer period of time and its value does change then there would be gain or loss, its long-term or short-term character depending on the length of time the ring is held before being sold.
The advice that “it might be beneficial to sell the ring under someone else's name” is tantamount to fraud unless the ring is the subject of a bona fide gift to the other person. That would require the finder to wash their hands of any involvement in the decision of the done to sell or not sell the ring or any of the details with respect to any sale. The idea of having someone else “report the sale” is downright dangerous advice.
So what grade would I give the answer if the question were an examination question and the answer came from a student in the course? My method of grading examinations generates scores, which are then combined with scores from other facets of the course to generate a course grade. The examination contains more than one question, so the best I can do is to offer two conclusions. First, this answer would earn zero points. Second, if this question was the only question on the examination and there were no other score-generating activities in the course, the course grade would be an F.
If I were to put a question as simple as this one on an examination it, along with one or two others, would fall into a category designed to make it easy for a student to show that they learned at least something in the course, and scoring well on those questions, and only on those questions, would bring the course grade to a D. In my grading construct, the D is the grade indicating “well, at least you learned something.”
For those who, not unlike students, would argue that the answer indicates a knowledge of short-term and long-term capital gain rates, my response is that the question did not seek any discussion of that point. One of many skills that need to be acquired or polished in law school – in fact, in every discipline – is to answer the question that is asked and not the question the person wishes would have been asked. To see how this works in the practice world, check out any Judge Judy episode when she asks a question and gets an answer that isn’t an answer to the question she asked. And let’s not mention the negative effect of the horrible advice to put the sale in another person’s name.
Monday, August 12, 2024
Some Tips About Tips and Taxes
Why would this proposal do little or nothing for workers who rely on tips? According to several reports, such as this one from Axios, and this one from Alternet, Alex Morash of the advocacy group One Fair Wage, in a report compiled in collaboration of the University of California at Berkeley Food Labor Research Center, concluded that nearly one-half of tipped workers in restaurants earn less than the $13,850 cutoff for paying federal income taxes. About two-thirds of them live in households with income too low to create federal income tax liability. In other words, excluding tip income from the gross incomes of these workers does absolutely nothing for them. I think the number of workers who would not benefit is even higher, because these computations apparently do not take into account any credits to which the workers may be entitled to claim. This conclusion is supported by analyses offered by the Tax Policy Center. And if tips are exempted from employment taxes, it jeopardizes the eligibility of tipped workers for Social Security and Medicare coverage or reduces what they are eligible to collect.
So who would benefit from excluding tip income from gross income? Most likely, the small percentage of tipped workers who collect large amounts of tips. Those workers, estimated to constitute about 5 to 10 percent of tipped workers, gather their tips at luxury hotels and restaurants. Though they would welcome a reduction in their federal income tax liabilities, assuming they have any, in the long run it would work to their detriment. Let’s see why.
Cutting federal income taxes on tips gives the employers of tipped workers another argument against raising the minimum wage or at least reducing any increase. Though excluding tips from gross income would benefit only a small percentage of tipped workers, the concept would help employers spare themselves the expense of raising wages for all workers, including those who are barely getting by even with tip income.
Who else might benefit? Tips are nothing more than another form of compensation for the performance of services. It should make no difference whether money flows directly from a customer to a worker or from the customer to the worker through the employer. In both instances the worker is receiving compensation. If the handful of tipped workers who pay taxes on their tips should be excused from doing so because they are perceived to be earning insufficient income, then the same benefit should be given to all other workers who are earning the similar amounts of insufficient income. In other words, raise the standard deduction or make adjustments in the tax rate schedules rather than singling out one class of worker for special treatment.
Then there are those who would manipulate the system to convert non-tip forms of compensation into tips. Already there are planners thinking about ways to make this happen. It’s not my intention to provide blueprints for this sort of behavior other than to note that it is possible. Imagine the impact on the economy, to say nothing of the operation of government, if suddenly all wage earners were being paid minimum wage and the rest of their pay in “tips.” It could be worse, as clever planners find ways to convert partnership and S corporation distributions, C corporation dividends, and other forms of income into “tips.” At least the presumptive nominee for one major political party includes in the proposal plans to find ways to prevent this from happening.
Of course, as is the case with many special interest tax provisions, the proposal is nothing more than a band-aid designed to soften rather than address the impact of the underlying problem. Even if the proposal to exclude tips from gross income was a sincere effort to help underpaid workers and not a vote-grabbing ploy in the state where it was announced, a state where a high proportion of workers rely on tips, it is a feeble excuse of a solution for the problem of underpaid workers. There needs to be an increase in the federal minimum wage, which has not been changed since 2009. Even though some states have stepped up to deal with this Congressional neglect, there are workers in states that have not done anything to deal with the problem. Worse, the federal minimum wage is sharply reduced for workers in industries where tipping is the norm, so long as the tips bring the worker’s hourly pay up to the federal minimum wage. This exception encourages tipping.
Tipping is a major ingredient of American culture. It’s different in other countries, where workers are paid a living wage and do not need to rely on the decisions of customers. Though many customers tip based on the quality of service, too many cut tips if they are unhappy with other aspects of their experience beyond the control of the tipped worker, too many don’t leave tips (or leave very tiny tips) because they “don’t believe in tipping,” too many “forget” to tip, and too many, including the many tourists from other countries, simply don’t understand the tipping culture. Making a shift from the “American way” of compensating workers in certain service industries to the pattern in place in other countries would be difficult but not impossible, and in the long run far more efficient.
Those who oppose changing the culture of tipping want to retain “a way to show the business that its services is terrible.” The way to show a business that its service is terrible is to stop patronizing the business. Then the business in theory fixes the problems or goes out of business. If the problem is the worker, the worker needs to be retrained or released. If the problem is something else, as it often is though “taken out” on the worker through a reduced or eliminated tip, then the business either fixes the problem or goes out of business.
Once again, it is apparent that blurting out something that “sounds good” in a sound bite or tweet isn’t so good when the idea is subjected to examination, analysis, and critical thinking. Very few Americans understand the full ramifications of a simple “stop taxing tips” ploy. It’s not that simple.
Tuesday, August 06, 2024
Tax Might Be Boring, But the Underlying Facts Often Are Not
The case that reader Morris brought to my attention interested me not only because of the tax issues, which are actually very straight-forward, but also because of the underlying facts. A young woman, who was tired of attending family events by herself because everyone else was married or had a significant other, hired a young man to pretend to be her date for Thanksgiving weekend with her family. She found the fellow on a website that provides a platform for those who want a date to contact those who are willing to be, as the judge put it, “fake dates.” The young woman not only paid the young man $750 per day for the four days, but also paid about $2,400 to cover the cost of his flight, hotel room, and transportation. One of the terms of the contract was that the young man’s status as a fake date was not to be revealed.
Things went well the first day. One of the young woman’s cousins who was at the family gathering stayed, with her boyfriend, at the same hotel at which the young man was staying. On Thursday night or Friday morning, the cousin broke up with her boyfriend because he was getting multiple phone calls from another woman, with whom he met up after the breakup. When the “fake date” showed up at the family home he was accompanied by the cousin, and the two of them were being very affectionate. According to the young woman who hired the date, he pretty much ignored her and focused on the cousin.
After the four-day date ended, unbeknownst to the young woman, the young man entered into a relationship with the cousin. About a month later, when the young woman’s family held its Christmas gathering, the young man showed up with the cousin, as boyfriend and girlfriend. Things took a bad turn when the cousin “told everyone” that the supposed boyfriend of the young woman was a “fake date” hired by her. It turns out that the young man had told the cousin about the hired date arrangement in order to assure her that he was not in a relationship with the young woman.
The young woman sued the “fake date” for a return of the $5,400 that she had paid directly to him and to provide him transportation and lodging. Judge Perez declared that it was the easiest case she had heard all week, and held in favor of the young woman for the full $5,400.
Reader Morris asked me four questions: “Does the defendant have gross income? Is it business income on Schedule C? Does the Plaintiff have any federal tax consequences? Can the defendant deduct the judgement for breach of contract as a business expense on his Schedule C?”
My answer was rather short. “Yes, the defendant has gross income that is reported on Schedule C. The defendant also offsets gross income by the amount refunded to the plaintiff, just as any service provider refunds a customer when the service fails to comply with the contract. Thus there is no need for a deduction. The plaintiff has no tax consequences because the transactions were personal in nature and not connected with a trade or business or for-profit activity.”
The tax conclusions aren’t novel or complex or bewildering. The underlying facts, though, are far more interesting than, for example, a lawn service customer suing a lawn maintenance company for damaging trees or breaking a fence. When people tell me that tax is boring, I reply that it often is but the underlying stories are what makes it interesting.
Monday, July 22, 2024
Internal Revenue Code Component (aa) Has Been Given a Name
Yesterday reader Morris sent me an email captioned, “The search of 14 years is over.” I must confess that during those 14 years I had not been actively searching for an answer. But reader Morris came upon what appears to be an answer.
According to this Wikipedia article, the name for (aa) and (bb) is item, and the name for the next component, (AA) and (BB), etc., is subitem. The Wikipedia article, apparently written in 2018, and updated in 2021, cites two sources, one of which I cannot find though it has been archived. The other source, the Detailed Guide to the United State Code Content and Features from the Office of the Law Revision Counsel for the United States Code, states, “Sections are often subdivided into a combination of smaller units such as subsections, paragraphs, subparagraphs, clauses, subclauses, and items.“ The Guide does provide a date for its creation or updates. The Wikipedia article citation to the Guide states, “Archived from the original on November 26, 2022. Retrieved February 2, 2021.”
It appears that the designation of “item” and “subitem” for the (aa) and (AA) components of the Internal Revenue Code is a fairly recent development. I’m certain that when the Guide was first written there was no need for those designations because legislation had not become as complicated as it now is, creating the need for deep levels of substructures.
If I were still teaching the introductory federal income taxation course, I would need to update the materials I provided to the students. Though I am no longer teaching that course, I decided to provide this update to the question so that those who do teach the course and give attention to the structure of the Internal Revenue Code (and Treasury Regulations) can update their materials. Because I know that there are at least a handful of law faculty using parts of the materials I developed it made sense to me to share this new information (that came to me thanks to reader Morris). I also figured that readers of this blog, many of whom are tax professionals or otherwise interested in tax, would benefit from knowing that (aa) and (AA) have been given names.
Friday, July 12, 2024
So You Want to Pay Zero Taxes?
So who can set up their finances to fit within the advice? Someone who earns their income by working? No, because wages are not long-term capital gains and they aren’t qualified dividends. Someone who adds to their wages by putting money in the bank an earning some interest? No, because interest payments are not long-term capital gains and they aren’t qualified dividends.
So who can arrange their finances so that their income consists of long-term capital gains and qualified dividends? Someone who has sufficient capital to generate $94,050 of those items. How much capital is required depends on the rates of return that one assumes would apply. A safe guess would be somewhere in the vicinity of $1.5 to $2.0 million.
But there’s another catch. If a person with sufficient capital to generate this sort of income also has wages, interest, or other ordinary income, some or all of the untaxed $123,250 will be taxed. So who’s still eligible to do the “pay zero taxes” thing? Someone with sufficient but not too much capital, who keeps their qualified long-term capital gains and qualified dividends within the zero-tax range, who doesn’t need or have any other type of income. There aren’t very many people who will end up taking advantage of the “pay zero tax” arrangement.
So it’s understandable when most Americans consider the federal income tax to be skewed in favor of the investing class and not workers. It is so skewed. What is missing in most instances is taking the next step, from recognizing the biases in the federal income tax, understanding how and why they came to exist, and then taking steps to vote for legislators who are willing to change the law so that it doesn’t disfavor those who need to work to make a living. That’s a tall order, because those who benefit from the skewed income tax law are the ones with the wherewithal to finance the campaigns of legislators who are unwilling to balance the income tax law but rather want to make it even more favorable to those who benefit from the imbalance. And, no, throwing a few crumbs to low-income wage earners does very little to help them and does nothing for the disappearing middle class.
I understand why people don’t want to pay taxes. People don’t want to pay for anything, at least until (and unless) they think about the consequences of trying to get something for nothing. Most people understand that trying to get a person to mow their lawn for free, or serve them a restaurant meal for free, is wrong for so many reasons, both legally and morally. Yet they don’t have the same hesitation when it comes to trying to get public services for free. I think the reason is that there is a more attenuated connection between taxes and public services than there is between the direct payment to the lawn mowing person or the restaurant. And that is where the education system has failed the nation, because too many people do not realize the extent of the public services they receive without being aware that they are benefitting. Why? Because they take them for granted.
So, no, I have no interest, if even I could somehow fit within the suggested financial structure, in paying zero taxes. Why? Because I know that if I pay no taxes I ought not expect anyone else to pay taxes. And I know what would happen if no one paid taxes. I do wish everyone else also would know what would happen. Then the “pay zero taxes” ploys would fall on deaf ears.
Wednesday, June 26, 2024
A Mileage-Based Road Fee by Any Other Name?
What caught my attention wasn’t the pilot program, but something written about it by Andrew Leahy in Week in Insights: California ‘Road Charge’ Is Sensible, if Flawed. He wrote, “The ‘road charge’ should really be a ‘transportation charge.’ And it should transparently break down how the funds raised will be allotted to road maintenance, public transit, climate change initiatives, and state remediation programs.” I tried to find information about the intended use of the California road charge revenue other than for road repair and maintenance, but I was unsuccessful. If indeed some of the revenue is earmarked for public transit, climate change initiatives, and state remediation programs, then it violates the principle that user fees should be directed to the goods or services for which the fees are being paid. I understand, for example, that one might argue that a person using a highway ought to pay for the “privilege” of avoiding the use of public transit, but considering the awful state of public transit in this nation, that sort of reasoning would lead to the concept of public transit riders paying road users for refraining from overburdening inadequate public transit facilities.
Of course, changing the word “road” to “transportation” doesn’t change the underlying question of the uses to which the revenues are put. The word “transportation” would make sense if the fee were to be applied not only to the use of roads, but also the use of airports, air space, rivers, ports, and railroad tracks. Of course, the use of the word “road” neglects the fact that drivers also use bridges, tunnels, and rest areas. But “road” suffices to convey the message. The word “transportation” would suggest uses for other transport functions and if the revenue is directed to non-transportation purposes would be as inadequate as the word “road.” Directing revenue to other purposes would give the fee too much of a resemblance to a tax. And changing the word “fee” to “tax” would make it even more challenging to persuade people and legislatures to adopt the mileage-based road fee.
Monday, June 10, 2024
More Attempts to Squash the IRS and the 98 Percent
According to many sources, including this report, the most recent maneuver in this attempt to put more money in the pockets of the wealthy is legislation that would cut the IRS budget by 18 percent. Most of the cut would affect IRS enforcement spending. At the moment, the legislation has no chance of being enacted, but that will change in 2025 if Republicans manage to take control of Congress and the White House.
This is far from the first time I have written about the efforts of wealthy individuals to escape taxation. In Cutting Off the Tax Revenue Nose to Spite a Political Face, I explained how similar legislation was introduced last year was defended on the false claim that the IRS focuses its enforcement efforts on taxpayers with less than $400,000 of annual income. This claim is intended to rally support among those who, if they understood what is happening, would vote overwhelmingly to remove from office these friends of the wealthy. In a previous commentary, Fear Mongering, Tax Style, I explained why that claim, and the claim that the IRS would hire nearly 100,000 new auditors, were lies, and why they find “fertile ground in the hearts and minds of those who react quickly to emotions and fail for one reason or another to think critically and dissect the absurdity of the claims.”
I’ve previously pointed out how Republicans plan to offset some of the revenue loss created by their intended shrinkage of the IRS and gifting of more tax breaks to the wealthy. They plan to go after Social Security and Medicare. In January the same crew that is trying to cut the IRS enforcement budget pushed through another doomed effort, that is, doomed until and unless Republicans take control in 2025, to cut Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, in the enticingly but deceptively named Fiscal Commission Act.
It continues to amaze me how so many people will vote for candidates who plan to support legislation that works to the detriment of most of their supporters. Will they ever learn?
Monday, May 27, 2024
Freedom To Do or Freedom From or Both?
Three years ago, in The Price of Freedom Is Much More Than Taxes. I addressed the connection between the payment of taxes and the things people take for granted as part of their “freedom.” More than a decade ago, 2011, I had written, in Free, Freedom, Fees, and Taxes, that “In order for a person to have something for free, someone else must pay.”
Last year, in Indeed, Freedom Is Not Free, I explained why freedom is not the same thing as unregulated behavior, pointing out that people who think they are free to drive 90 miles per hour on a 55-mile-per-hour highway, free to run red lights, free to shoplift, free to do whatever they want no matter what have a warped sense of the meaning of freedom. I wrote this about unregulated freedom:
Too often, those who claim that this unregulated “freedom” is sacrosanct point to the arrival of Puritans in what is now Massachusetts. They are idolized as seekers of freedom, trying to escape religious and political persecution. Yet when they arrived in the Massachusetts Bay Colony, they immediately started acting in the same manner as had their tormenters, in turn suppressing those whose religious beliefs or political positions conflicted with those set down by the Puritans. The contrast with Pennsylvania, also settled by victims of religious persecution, but where those of diverse origins and religions were welcomed, is startling. I didn’t learn this in school because it isn’t taught in this manner, nor is this lesson noted. I learned this when I did the research to write the biography of Thomas Maule of Salem, reading not only his works and those of others, both in his day and thereafter, but also studying the social and cultural environment in which his fellow citizens, of a different religious persuasion, acquitted him of the seditious libel charges brought by Puritan authorities who resented being tagged as hypocrites. And they truly were. Seem familiar? Today the nation is being tormented by “freedom lovers” who are trying to prevent Americans from learning the truth about the hypocritical Puritans whom they not only worship but whose hypocrisy they emulate and imitate.I then asked a question, specifically, “What sort of ‘freedom’ will this nation embrace?” I contrasted two models. One is the “freedom” to escape torment and persecution only to torment and persecute others. The other is the “freedom” to welcome those with different perspectives while refusing to adopt the methods of those from whom freedom was sought.
It is the first model that I want to consider. It requires a contrast between “freedom to do” and “freedom from.” In some respects those two phrases express the same concept. “Freedom to do” is, after all, simply “freedom from” regulation and “freedom from” authority. Yet there is a conflict, because one person’s “freedom to do” whatever they want conflicts with another person’s “freedom from” whatever it is the first person is doing. In realistic terms, “freedom to do” 90 miles per hour on the highway conflicts with another person’s “freedom from” injury and death while driving.
What makes the analysis particularly difficult on Memorial Day is a troubling tension between “freedom from” and “freedom to do.” On Memorial Day we remember and honor those who died to give this nation “freedom from” authoritarianism, dictatorship, repression, and ethnocentrism. Yet we also seem increasingly complacent when those who benefitted from the sacrifice of those we honor claim to have the “freedom to do” the very same behaviors the suppression of which was the purpose for which those we honor fought and died. It is particularly disturbing when people who profess a deep admiration for those who gave their lives to protect the nation from those enumerated evils are at the same time supporting people and policies that nurture and enlarge those same evils in this nation. What was the point of so many sacrifices to eliminate authoritarianism, dictatorship, repression, and ethnocentrism when there are people who want those same attributes to become the linchpin of this nation’s existence?
So there is both a freedom to do and a freedom from, but both freedoms are, as I pointed out, two sides to the same coin. And whether considered as one or two, freedom not only is not free, but it also is not unlimited. One person’s freedom exists within the boundary created by the freedoms of other persons. Removing that boundary invites and fuels chaos, catastrophe, and ultimately freedom for no one because no one will be left. This time around the end of civilization is the end of the species. All the parades, picnics, hot dogs, beach trips, ceremonies, and social meme posting will mean nothing if the meaning and scope of freedom is misunderstood by increasing numbers of people. It’s time to remember that rights only exist if responsibilities thrive.
Tuesday, May 14, 2024
A Public-Private Partnership Highway Toll Fiasco Narrowly Averted
Today, reader Morris directed my attention to yet another very big mistake made by the legislature in Texas. In a story about an increase in the number of toll roads in Texas,** a former Texas state representative admitted that “Texas made a mistake.” According to the story, in 2007 Cintra, a private toll company, won its bid to build part of a new toll road in Collin County. The road would cost $500 million to build. The company, based in Spain, offered $2.7 million to take over the project, in exchange for its right to receive the next 52 years of tolls. Eventually someone figured out that the expected revenue stream from only the first 40 years of tolls flowing to the Spanish company would amount to $34 billion. In other words, Texas would be giving up $34 billion of revenue in exchange for $2.7 billion up front. Even taking into account the costs of operating, maintaining, and repairing the road would cut into the net revenue from the project, this clearly was a “private sector wins, state of Texas and its residents lose” deal. Worse, the contract prohibited Texas from increasing the capacity of free roads that connected to the toll road, and also prohibited the state from buying back toll roads from the private companies. Fortunately, these problems were caught in time by the administrative agency that handles transportation in Texas and it rescinded the contract.
Why are these deals bad? The reason is simple. The public-private deal creates profits for the private sector, and to fund those profits taxpayers and toll payers are required to pay more than they would if the public function remained public. Why do legislatures fall for these deals? Because they want to be re-elected and that requires support from the private sector, specifically the segment of the private sector that controls the huge amounts of money involved in these deals.
There’s another lesson lurking in this story. It was the administrative agency, not the legislature, that listened to people who understand the complexity of these deals and saved Texas residents. It’s no surprise, therefore, that certain legislators across the country, including some in the nation’s capital, are trying to eliminate, disempower, and curtail administrative agencies. Those agencies are where the expertise resides. It doesn’t reside in legislatures, in part because legislators need to allocate time among thousands of issues which leaves them no time to get into details, and in part because far too many legislators invest increasing amounts of time to re-election attempts and distracting political theater.
** The entire article (and its scheduled follow-up) is worth reading for an examination of what happens when the refusal to impose or increase taxes coupled with handing over government functions to private domestic and foreign companies causes a variety of problems extending beyond the question of who pockets toll revenues. Highway fatalities, erroneous loss of vehicle registrations, criminal prosecutions controlled by toll companies, and a long list of other problems plague the state.
Monday, April 29, 2024
Taxpayer’s Argument in Sales Tax Case Falls Flat
Reader Morris has directed my attention to a decision by the Commonwealth Court of Pennsylvania that addressed the question of whether Perrier carbonated natural mineral water is water exempt from the sales tax or a soft drink subject to the sales tax. The court explained that the product is a soft drink because it is carbonated using the same process used to carbonate soft drinks. The court relied on the definition of “soft drink” in the statute, which includes “carbonated water.”
As I’ve also pointed out, those who practice tax law learn, and must learn, all sorts of things that are beyond the statutes, regulations, and other authorities that set forth the law of taxation. In this instance I learned that Perrier carbonated natural mineral water isn’t simply natural carbonated mineral water extracted from underground. Instead, the mineral water and the carbonic gas are extracted separately from the same geological formation and then are combined through a process that involves removing impurities, chilling the water, and removing air from the water. Surprisingly, any carbonation in the harvested water is removed before the carbonic gas extracted from a different area in the geological formation is added.
This case is an interesting illustration of why legislatures need to do what attorneys need to do. Before drafting legislation, and while reviewing legislation as it moves through the legislature, legislators should acquire as much information as possible so that they can craft statutes that answer questions. In this situation, because of the arguable ambiguity in the statute concerning the differences between water and soft drink, the legislature could have simply inserted the word “noncarbonated” before the word “water” in the section of the statute exempting water from the sales tax or the phrase “artificially” before the phrase “carbonated water” in the definition of “soft drink.” Either of these tweaks, or any other that would align with what the legislature intended once it made itself aware of the uncertain status of Perrier water would have spared the litigants the cost and time invested in the litigation, and would have reduced the court’s docket by at least one case. On the other hand, if the statute had been so drafted, I and others might have continued with our ignorance with respect to how Perrier carbonated natural mineral water is produced unless some other reason caused us to research the question.
I close by tipping my hat to the court for its clever work with the English language. No, I’m not talking about the word “water” and the phrase “soft drink.” I’m referring to this sentence from the court’s opinion: “The issues raised before this Court bubble down to one question.” With the court’s decision, barring a reversal on appeal, the ongoing dispute between the taxpayers and the Department of Revenue over this issue has fizzled out.
Tuesday, April 23, 2024
When Preparing False Tax Returns Seems to Lack a Financial Motive
Today, the Department of Justice issued a press release describing the sentencing of a woman who had prepared more than 900 false tax returns. According to the press release, these fraudulent returns were prepared from at least January 2017 through June 2023. By claiming unjustified deductions, the preparer obtained for her clients larger refunds than they otherwise would have received. The IRS paid roughly $1.3 million in these fraudulent refunds.
The preparer charged at least $300 for each return that was prepared. That means that over seven tax preparation seasons the preparer collected at least $270,000. That’s only $38,571 annually. It is unclear if this was the total income collected by the preparer over those years from preparing returns, or if other returns also were prepared for which the preparer charged but did not subject to false deductions and credits. It also is unclear if the preparer had other income. I mention this because trying to live on $38,000 annually is difficult.
The preparer was sentence to one year and one day in prison, and to serve one year of supervised release. The preparer also was ordered to pay $1,349,314 in restitution to the IRS. The sentence leaves me with two questions.
First, was the preparer prohibited from resuming the tax return preparation business when released from prison? If not, why not?
Second, did the IRS recover from the preparer’s clients the $1.3 million in fraudulent refunds, and if so, then will the Treasury receive those amounts along with the restitution that the preparer has been ordered to pay? If so, does this constitute a sort of “double dipping” that ought not be permitted? Or should the $1.3 million that the preparer has been ordered to repay as restitution be more properly characterized as a fine or penalty, which would remove the specter of “double dipping” from the situation?
Other questions are not prompted by the sentence. Would the preparer have charged less than $300 for a return if the return did not include false deductions? Did the clients know about the false deductions? If the answers to those questions are “no,” then why not simply prepare false-free returns? I ask, because being required to pay more than $1.3 million and to sit in prison for a year is quite the price to pay in order to collect $270,000 in income, especially if that income could have been collected by preparing false-free returns. Something doesn’t add up.